Filter and Search through this List
[1] D. H. Blackwell :
Some properties of Markoff chains .
Ph.D. thesis ,
University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign ,
1941 .
Advised by J. L. Doob .
MR
2937439
phdthesis
People
BibTeX
@phdthesis {key2937439m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David H.},
TITLE = {Some properties of {M}arkoff chains},
SCHOOL = {University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign},
YEAR = {1941},
URL = {http://search.proquest.com/docview/301831767},
NOTE = {Advised by J. L. Doob. MR:2937439.},
}
[2] D. Blackwell :
“Idempotent Markoff chains ,”
Ann. Math. (2)
43 : 3
(July 1942 ),
pp. 560–567 .
MR
0006632
Zbl
0063.00419
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( \mathcal{B} \) be any Borel field of subsets of an abstract space \( X \) , and suppose that for each \( x\in X \) a probability measure \( P(x,E) \) is defined on \( \mathcal{B} \) and that \( P(x,E) \) is for fixed \( E \) a \( \mathcal{B} \) -measurable function of \( x \) . Then \( P(x,E) \) may be considered as representing the transition probability of going from the point \( x \) into the set \( E \) in a single trial, and it is said to determine a Markoff chain on \( X \) . The probability of going from \( x \) into \( E \) in \( n \) trials, denoted by \( P_n(x,E) \) , is given inductively by
\begin{equation*}\tag{1} P_n(x,E) = \int P(y,E)\,dP_{n-1}(x,y). \end{equation*}
In this paper we shall consider Markoff chains for which \( P_n(x,E) \) is independent of \( n \) . It is clear from (1) that this will occur whenever \( P_2(x,E) = P(x, E) \) , so that we shall be studying Markoff chains which satisfy
\[ P(x,E) = \int P(y,E)\,dP(x,y). \]
Such a Markoff chain will be called idempotent, and the justification for this is apparent.
@article {key0006632m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Idempotent {M}arkoff chains},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. (2)},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematics. Second Series},
VOLUME = {43},
NUMBER = {3},
MONTH = {July},
YEAR = {1942},
PAGES = {560--567},
DOI = {10.2307/1968811},
NOTE = {MR:0006632. Zbl:0063.00419.},
ISSN = {0003-486X},
}
[3] D. Blackwell :
“The existence of anormal chains ,”
Bull. Am. Math. Soc.
51 : 6, Part 1
(1945 ),
pp. 465–468 .
MR
0011916
Zbl
0063.00420
article
BibTeX
@article {key0011916m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The existence of anormal chains},
JOURNAL = {Bull. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Bulletin of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {51},
NUMBER = {6, Part 1},
YEAR = {1945},
PAGES = {465--468},
DOI = {10.1090/S0002-9904-1945-08378-5},
NOTE = {MR:0011916. Zbl:0063.00420.},
ISSN = {0002-9904},
}
[4] D. Blackwell :
“Finite non-homogeneous chains ,”
Ann. Math. (2)
46 : 4
(October 1945 ),
pp. 594–599 .
MR
0013858
Zbl
0063.00421
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( X \) denote the set of integers \( {}1 \) , \( 2,\dots \) , \( N \) , considered as the possible states of a physical system, and denote by \( P_{ij}(r,s) \) the probability that the system is in state \( j \) at time \( s \) under the hypothesis that it is in state \( i \) at time \( r \) , where \( r < s \) , \( r, s = \dots, -1 \) , \( 0,1,\dots \) . The \( N{\times}N \) matrices \( P(r,s) \) with elements \( P_{ij}(r,s) \) will be Markoff matrices, i.e. matrices with non-negative elements and row sums unity, and we shall suppose that they satisfy the equation
\[ P(r,s)\,P(s,t) = P(r,t) \quad\text{for }r < s < t .\]
This equation represents the condition that the successive states of the system form a Markoff chain, i.e. the probability that the system is in state \( j \) at time \( s \) under the hypothesis that it is in state \( i \) at time \( r \) (\( r < s \) ) is independent of any hypotheses concerning the states of the system at instants prior to \( r \) . A set of \( 1{\times}N \) Markoff matrices \( P(s) \) will be called a set of absolute probabilities if the equation
\[ P(s)\,P(s,t) = P(t) \quad\text{for }s < t \]
holds. Kolmogoroff [1935] has shown that sets of absolute probabilities always exist and will be unique under certain conditions; it will be easy to show that there are never more than \( N \) linearly independent such sets. Using these facts, together with a theorem of Doob asserting the convergence of a sequence of chance variables satisfying certain conditions, we investigate the asymptotic properties of the matrices \( P(r,s) \) and the associated stochastic processes. Our principal result, Theorem 3, shows that the properties of non-homogeneous chains are analogous to those well known in the homogeneous case where \( P(r,s) \) depends only on \( s - r \) .
@article {key0013858m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Finite non-homogeneous chains},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. (2)},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematics. Second Series},
VOLUME = {46},
NUMBER = {4},
MONTH = {October},
YEAR = {1945},
PAGES = {594--599},
DOI = {10.2307/1969199},
NOTE = {MR:0013858. Zbl:0063.00421.},
ISSN = {0003-486X},
}
[5] D. Blackwell and M. A. Girshick :
“On functions of sequences of independent chance vectors with applications to the problem of the ‘random walk’ in \( k \) dimensions ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
17 : 3
(September 1946 ),
pp. 310–317 .
MR
0017898
Zbl
0060.29007
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Consider a sequence \( \{x_i\} \) of independent chance vectors in \( k \) dimensions with identical distributions, and a sequence of mutually exclusive events \( S_1 \) , \( S_2, \dots \) , such that \( S_i \) depends only on the first \( i \) vectors and \( \sum P(S_i) = 1 \) . Let \( \varphi_i \) be a real or complex function of the first \( i \) vectors in the sequence satisfying conditions:
\( E(\varphi_i) = 0 \) and
\( E(\varphi_j \mid X_1, \dots, X_i) = \varphi_i \) for \( j \geq i \) .
Let \( \varphi = \varphi_i \) and \( n = i \) when \( S_i \) occurs. A general theorem is proved which gives the conditions \( \varphi_i \) must satisfy such that \( E\varphi = 0 \) . This theorem generalizes some of the important results obtained by Wald for \( k = 1 \) . A method is also given for obtaining the distribution of \( \varphi \) and \( n \) in the problem of the ”random walk” in \( k \) dimensions for the case in which the components of the vector take on a finite number of integral values.
@article {key0017898m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Girshick, M. A.},
TITLE = {On functions of sequences of independent
chance vectors with applications to
the problem of the ``random walk'' in
\$k\$ dimensions},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {17},
NUMBER = {3},
MONTH = {September},
YEAR = {1946},
PAGES = {310--317},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177730943},
NOTE = {MR:0017898. Zbl:0060.29007.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[6] D. Blackwell :
“On an equation of Wald ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
17 : 1
(March 1946 ),
pp. 84–87 .
MR
0019902
Zbl
0063.00422
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( X_1, X_2, \dots \) be a sequence of independent chance variables with a common expected value \( a \) , and let \( S_1 \) , \( S_2, \dots \) be a sequence of mutually exclusive events, \( S_k \) depending only on \( X_1,\dots \) , \( X_k \) , such that
\[ \sum_{k=1}^{\infty}P(S_k)=1 .\]
Define the chance variables
\[ n=n(X_1,X_2,\dots)=k \]
when \( S_k \) occurs and
\[ W=X_1+\dots + X_n .\]
We shall consider conditions under which the equation \( E(W) = aE(n) \) , due to Wald [1945, p. 142], holds.
@article {key0019902m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On an equation of {W}ald},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {17},
NUMBER = {1},
MONTH = {March},
YEAR = {1946},
PAGES = {84--87},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177731028},
NOTE = {MR:0019902. Zbl:0063.00422.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[7] D. Blackwell :
“Conditional expectation and unbiased sequential estimation ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
18 : 1
(1947 ),
pp. 105–110 .
MR
0019903
Zbl
0033.07603
article
Abstract
BibTeX
It is shown that
\[ E\bigl[ f(x) \,E(y \mid x)\bigr] = E(fy) \]
whenever \( E(fy) \) is finite, and that
\[ \sigma^2 E(y \mid x) \leq \sigma^2 y ,\]
where \( E(y \mid x) \) denotes the conditional expectation of \( y \) with respect to \( x \) . These results imply that whenever there is a sufficient statistic \( u \) and an unbiased estimate \( t \) , not a function of \( u \) only, for a parameter \( \theta \) , the function \( E(t \mid u) \) , which is a function of \( u \) only, is an unbiased estimate for \( \theta \) with a variance smaller than that of \( t \) . A sequential unbiased estimate for a parameter is obtained, such that when the sequential test terminates after \( i \) observations, the estimate is a function of a sufficient statistic for the parameter with respect to these observations. A special case of this estimate is that obtained by Girshick, Mosteller, and Savage [1946] for the parameter of a binomial distribution.
@article {key0019903m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Conditional expectation and unbiased
sequential estimation},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {18},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1947},
PAGES = {105--110},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177730497},
NOTE = {MR:0019903. Zbl:0033.07603.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[8] D. Blackwell and M. A. Girshick :
“A lower bound for the variance of some unbiased sequential estimates ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
18 : 2
(June 1947 ),
pp. 277–280 .
MR
0020765
Zbl
0032.04401
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Consider a sequence of independent chance variables \( x_1 \) , \( x_2,\dots \) with identical distributions determined by an unknown parameter \( \theta \) . We assume that \( Ex_i=\theta \) and that
\[ W_k = x_1 + \dots + x_k \]
is a sufficient statistic for estimating \( \theta \) from \( x_1,\dots \) , \( x_k \) . A sequential sampling procedure is defined by a sequence of mutually exclusive events \( S_k \) such that \( S_k \) depends only on \( x_1,\dots \) , \( x_k \) and \( \sum P(S_k)=1 \) . Define \( W=W_k \) and \( n=k \) when \( S_k \) occurs. In a previous paper by one of the authors [Blackwell 1947] it was shown that if
\[ S_k = W_k C(S_1 + \dots + S_{k-1}) ,\]
(where \( C(A) \) denotes the event that \( A \) does not occur), the function
\[ V(W,n)=E(x_1\mid W,n) \]
is an unbiased estimate of \( \theta \) , and
\[ \sigma^2(V)\leq \sigma^2(x_1) .\]
It is the purpose of this note to obtain a lower bound for \( \sigma^2(V) \) . Our result is:
\( \displaystyle\sigma^2(V)\geq \frac{\sigma^2(x_1)}{E(n)} \)
@article {key0020765m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Girshick, M. A.},
TITLE = {A lower bound for the variance of some
unbiased sequential estimates},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {18},
NUMBER = {2},
MONTH = {June},
YEAR = {1947},
PAGES = {277--280},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177730444},
NOTE = {MR:0020765. Zbl:0032.04401.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[9] D. Blackwell :
“A renewal theorem ,”
Duke Math. J.
15 : 1
(1948 ),
pp. 145–150 .
MR
0024093
Zbl
0030.20102
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( x_i \) be independent non-negative chance variables with identical distributions. The asymptotic behavior of the expected number \( U(T) \) of sums
\[ s_k = x_1 + \dots +x_k \]
lying in the interval \( (0,T) \) has been studied by Feller [1941], using the integral equation of renewal theory and the method of Laplace transforms. Recently Doob [1948] has obtained as a consequence of general theorems on stationary Markov processes the following result: if the distribution of some \( s_k \) is non-singular, then
\[ U(T + h) - U(T) \to \frac{h}{E(x_1)} \]
as \( T\to\infty \) for every \( h > 0 \) . Täcklind [1945] has obtained an excellent estimate for \( U(T) \) itself: when the \( k \) -th moment of \( x_1 \) exists for some \( k > 2 \) and the values of \( x_1 \) are not all integral multiples of some fixed constant, his estimate shows at once that
\[ U(T + h) - U(T) \to \frac{h}{E(x_1)} .\]
In this paper we shall prove the following
Unless all values of \( x_1 \) are integral multiples of some fixed constant,
\[ U(T + h) - U(T) \to \frac{h}{E(x_1)} \qquad (T\to\infty) \]
for every \( h > 0 \) . (If \( E(x_1) = \infty \) , then \( h/E(x_1) \) is to be interpreted as zero.)
@article {key0024093m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {A renewal theorem},
JOURNAL = {Duke Math. J.},
FJOURNAL = {Duke Mathematical Journal},
VOLUME = {15},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1948},
PAGES = {145--150},
DOI = {10.1215/S0012-7094-48-01517-8},
NOTE = {MR:0024093. Zbl:0030.20102.},
ISSN = {0012-7094},
}
[10] K. J. Arrow, D. Blackwell, and M. A. Girshick :
“Bayes and minimax solutions of sequential decision problems ,”
Econometrica
17 : 3/4
(July–October 1949 ),
pp. 213–244 .
MR
0032173
Zbl
0034.07504
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
The present paper deals with the general problem of sequential choice among several actions, where at each stage the options available are to stop and take a definite action or to continue sampling for more information. There are costs attached to taking inappropriate action and to sampling. A characterization of the optimum solution is obtained first under very general assumptions as to the distribution of the successive observations and the costs of sampling; then more detailed results are given for the case where the alternative actions are finite in number, the observations are drawn under conditions of random sampling, and the cost depends only on the number of observations. Explicit solutions are given for the case of two actions, random sampling, and linear cost functions.
@article {key0032173m,
AUTHOR = {Arrow, K. J. and Blackwell, D. and Girshick,
M. A.},
TITLE = {Bayes and minimax solutions of sequential
decision problems},
JOURNAL = {Econometrica},
FJOURNAL = {Econometrica. Journal of the Econometric
Society},
VOLUME = {17},
NUMBER = {3/4},
MONTH = {July--October},
YEAR = {1949},
PAGES = {213--244},
DOI = {10.2307/1905525},
NOTE = {MR:0032173. Zbl:0034.07504.},
ISSN = {0012-9682},
}
[11] R. Bellman and D. Blackwell :
“Some two-person games involving bluffing ,”
Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U. S. A.
35 : 10
(October 1949 ),
pp. 600–605 .
MR
0031700
Zbl
0041.44805
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0031700m,
AUTHOR = {Bellman, Richard and Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Some two-person games involving bluffing},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U. S. A.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences of the United States of
America},
VOLUME = {35},
NUMBER = {10},
MONTH = {October},
YEAR = {1949},
PAGES = {600--605},
DOI = {10.1073/pnas.35.10.600},
NOTE = {MR:0031700. Zbl:0041.44805.},
ISSN = {0027-8424},
}
[12] D. Blackwell :
“On a theorem of Lyapunov ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
22 : 1
(March 1951 ),
pp. 112–114 .
MR
0039033
Zbl
0042.28502
article
Abstract
BibTeX
@article {key0039033m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On a theorem of {L}yapunov},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {22},
NUMBER = {1},
MONTH = {March},
YEAR = {1951},
PAGES = {112--114},
URL = {http://www.jstor.org/pss/2236708},
NOTE = {MR:0039033. Zbl:0042.28502.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[13] D. Blackwell :
“On the translation parameter problem for discrete variables ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
22 : 3
(September 1951 ),
pp. 393–399 .
MR
0043418
Zbl
0043.13802
article
Abstract
BibTeX
For any chance variable \( x = (x_1,\dots \) , \( x_N) \) having known distribution, the translation parameter estimation problem is to estimate an unknown constant \( h \) , having observed \( y = (x_1+h,\dots \) , \( x_N+h) \) . Extending the work of Pitman [1939], Girshick and Savage [1951] have, for any loss function depending only on the error of estimate, described an estimate whose risk is a constant \( R \) independent of \( h \) , and have shown that under certain hypotheses their estimate is minimax. We investigate whether the Girshick–Savage estimate is admissible, i.e., whether it is impossible to find an estimate with risk \( R(h)\leq R \) for all \( h \) and actual inequality for some \( h \) . We consider only bounded discrete variables \( x \) , and show that, if all values of \( x \) have all integer coordinates and if the loss \( f(d) \) from an error \( d \) is, for instance, strictly convex and assumes its minimum value, the Girshick–Savage estimate is admissible. Two examples in which the Girshick–Savage estimate is not admissible are given.
@article {key0043418m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On the translation parameter problem
for discrete variables},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {22},
NUMBER = {3},
MONTH = {September},
YEAR = {1951},
PAGES = {393--399},
URL = {http://www.jstor.org/pss/2236625},
NOTE = {MR:0043418. Zbl:0043.13802.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[14] R. Bellman and D. Blackwell :
“On moment spaces ,”
Ann. Math. (2)
54 : 2
(September 1951 ),
pp. 272–274 .
MR
0043866
Zbl
0044.12601
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key0043866m,
AUTHOR = {Bellman, Richard and Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On moment spaces},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. (2)},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematics. Second Series},
VOLUME = {54},
NUMBER = {2},
MONTH = {September},
YEAR = {1951},
PAGES = {272--274},
DOI = {10.2307/1969527},
NOTE = {MR:0043866. Zbl:0044.12601.},
ISSN = {0003-486X},
}
[15] D. Blackwell :
“Comparison of experiments ,”
pp. 93–102
in
Proceedings of the second Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability
(Berkeley, CA, 31 July–12 August 1950 ).
Edited by J. Neyman .
University of California Press (Berkeley and Los Angeles ),
1951 .
MR
0046002
Zbl
0044.14203
inproceedings
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Bohnenblust, Shapley, and Sherman [unpublished] have introduced a method of comparing two sampling procedures or experiments; essentially their concept is that one experiment \( \alpha \) is more informative than a second experiment \( \beta \) , \( \alpha\supset\beta \) , if, for every possible risk function, any risk attainable with \( \beta \) is also attainable with \( \alpha \) . If \( \alpha \) is a sufficient statistic for a procedure equivalent to \( \beta \) , \( \alpha\succ\beta \) , it is shown that \( \alpha\supset\beta \) . In the case of dichotomies, the converse is proved. Whether \( \succ \) and \( \supset \) are equivalent in general is not known. Various properties of \( \succ \) and \( \supset \) are obtained, such as the following: if \( \alpha\succ\beta \) and \( \gamma \) is independent of both, then the combination \( (\alpha,\gamma)\succ(\beta,\gamma) \) . An application to a problem in \( 2{\times}2 \) tables is discussed.
@inproceedings {key0046002m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Comparison of experiments},
BOOKTITLE = {Proceedings of the second {B}erkeley
symposium on mathematical statistics
and probability},
EDITOR = {Neyman, Jerzy},
PUBLISHER = {University of California Press},
ADDRESS = {Berkeley and Los Angeles},
YEAR = {1951},
PAGES = {93--102},
URL = {http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.bsmsp/1200500222},
NOTE = {(Berkeley, CA, 31 July--12 August 1950).
MR:0046002. Zbl:0044.14203.},
}
[16] D. Blackwell :
“The range of certain vector integrals ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
2 : 3
(September 1951 ),
pp. 390–395 .
MR
0041195
Zbl
0044.27702
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( u_1,\dots,u_n \) be completely additive set functions defined over a Borel field \( \mathcal{B} \) of subsets of a space \( X \) , and let \( A \) be any bounded subset of Euclidean \( n \) -space. With every \( \mathcal{B} \) -measurable function
\[ f=a(x) = [a_1(x),\dots,a_n(x)] \]
defined on \( X \) with range in \( A \) we associate the vector
\[ v(f) = \biggl(\int a_1(x)\,du_1,\dots,\int a_n(x)\,du_n\!\biggr) .\]
Our problem is to investigate the range \( R \) of the function \( v(f) \) .
@article {key0041195m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The range of certain vector integrals},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {2},
NUMBER = {3},
MONTH = {September},
YEAR = {1951},
PAGES = {390--395},
DOI = {10.2307/2031763},
NOTE = {MR:0041195. Zbl:0044.27702.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
}
[17] D. Blackwell :
“On randomization in statistical games with \( k \) terminal actions ,”
pp. 183–187
in
Contributions to the theory of games ,
vol. II .
Edited by H. W. Kuhn and A. W. Tucker .
Annals of Mathematics Studies 28 .
Princeton University Press ,
1953 .
MR
0054923
Zbl
0050.14801
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
In a two-person zero-sum game in which a player receives partial, i.e., statistical, information about his opponent’s strategy after which he takes one of \( k \) terminal actions, any randomized strategy is equivalent to a mixture of a countable number of pure strategies in the proportions
\[ \lambda_n = \Bigl(\frac{k-1}{k}\Bigr)^{n-1}\frac{1}{k}, \quad n = 1,2,\dots \]
The proof uses the fact that for any \( k \) non-negative numbers \( z_1,\dots \) , \( z_k \) with
\[ \sum_1^k z_i = 1 \]
there is a partition of the set of positive integers into disjoint sets \( S_1,\dots \) , \( S_k \) such that
\[ \sum_{n\in S_j}\lambda_n = z_j .\]
@incollection {key0054923m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On randomization in statistical games
with \$k\$ terminal actions},
BOOKTITLE = {Contributions to the theory of games},
EDITOR = {Kuhn, Harold William and Tucker, Albert
William},
VOLUME = {II},
SERIES = {Annals of Mathematics Studies},
NUMBER = {28},
PUBLISHER = {Princeton University Press},
YEAR = {1953},
PAGES = {183--187},
NOTE = {MR:0054923. Zbl:0050.14801.},
ISSN = {0066-2313},
ISBN = {9780691079356},
}
[18] D. Blackwell :
“Extension of a renewal theorem ,”
Pacific J. Math.
3 : 2
(1953 ),
pp. 315–320 .
MR
0054880
Zbl
0052.14104
article
Abstract
BibTeX
A chance variable \( x \) will be called a \( d \) -lattice variable if
\( \sum_{-\infty}^{\infty}Pr\{x=nd\} = 1 \) , and
\( d \) is the largest number for which (1) holds.
If \( x \) is not a \( d \) -lattice variable for any \( d \) , \( x \) will be called a nonlattice variable. The main purpose of this paper is to give a proof of:
Let \( x_1 \) , \( x_2, \dots \) be independent identically distributed chance variables with \( E(x_1) = m > 0 \) (the case \( m = +\infty \) is not excluded); let
\[ S_n = x_1 + \dots + x_n ;\]
and, for any \( h > 0 \) , let \( U(a,h) \) be the expected number of integers \( n\geq 0 \) for which \( a\leq S_n < a+h \) . If the \( x_n \) are nonlattice variables, then
\[ U(a,h)\to \frac{h}{m}, 0 \quad\textit{as }a\to +\infty,-\infty .\]
If the \( x_n \) are \( d \) -lattice variables, then
\[ U(a,d)\to \frac{d}{m}, 0 \quad\textit{as }a\to +\infty,-\infty .\]
(If \( m=+\infty \) , \( h/m \) and \( d/m \) are interpreted as zero.)
@article {key0054880m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Extension of a renewal theorem},
JOURNAL = {Pacific J. Math.},
FJOURNAL = {Pacific Journal of Mathematics},
VOLUME = {3},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1953},
PAGES = {315--320},
URL = {http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.pjm/1103051394},
NOTE = {MR:0054880. Zbl:0052.14104.},
ISSN = {0030-8730},
}
[19] K. J. Arrow, E. W. Barankin, and D. Blackwell :
“Admissible points of convex sets ,”
pp. 87–91
in
Contributions to the theory of games ,
vol. II .
Edited by H. W. Kuhn and A. W. Tucker .
Annals of Mathematics Studies 28 .
Princeton University Press ,
1953 .
MR
0054919
Zbl
0050.14203
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
A point \( s \) of a closed convex subset \( S \) of \( k \) -space is admissible if there is no \( t\in S \) with \( t_i\leq s_i \) for all \( i=1,\dots \) , \( k \) , \( t\neq s \) . An example is given in which the set \( A \) of admissible points is not closed.
Let \( P \) be the set of vectors \( p=(p_1,\dots \) , \( p_k) \) with \( p_i > 0 \) and \( \sum_1^k p_i=1 \) , let \( B(p) \) be the set of \( s\in S \) with
\[ (p,s)=\min_{t\in S}(p,t) ,\]
and let \( B=\sum B(p) \) , so that \( B \) consists of exactly those points of \( S \) at which there is a supporting hyperplane whose normal has positive components.
\( B\subset A\subset \overline{B} \) . If \( S \) is determined by a finite set, there is a finite set \( p_1,\dots \) , \( p_N \) , with \( p_j\in P \) , such that \( B=\sum_{j=1}^N B(p_j) \) , so that, since \( B(p) \) is closed for fixed \( p \) , \( B = A = \overline{B} \) .
@incollection {key0054919m,
AUTHOR = {Arrow, K. J. and Barankin, E. W. and
Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Admissible points of convex sets},
BOOKTITLE = {Contributions to the theory of games},
EDITOR = {Kuhn, Harold William and Tucker, Albert
William},
VOLUME = {II},
SERIES = {Annals of Mathematics Studies},
NUMBER = {28},
PUBLISHER = {Princeton University Press},
YEAR = {1953},
PAGES = {87--91},
NOTE = {MR:0054919. Zbl:0050.14203.},
ISSN = {0066-2313},
ISBN = {9780691079356},
}
[20] D. Blackwell :
“Equivalent comparisons of experiments ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
24 : 2
(1953 ),
pp. 265–272 .
MR
0056251
Zbl
0050.36004
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Sherman [1951] and Stein [1951] have shown that a method given by the author [Blackwell 1951] for comparing two experiments is equivalent, for experiments with a finite number of outcomes, to the original method introduced by Bohnenblust, Shapley, and Sherman [unpublished]. A new proof of this result is given, and the restriction to experiments with a finite number of outcomes is removed. A class of weaker comparisons — comparison in \( k \) -decision problems — is introduced, in three equivalent forms. For dichotomies, all methods are equivalent, and can be described in terms of errors of the first and second kinds.
@article {key0056251m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Equivalent comparisons of experiments},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {24},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1953},
PAGES = {265--272},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177729032},
NOTE = {MR:0056251. Zbl:0050.36004.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[21] N. M. Smith, Jr., S. S. Walters, F. C. Brooks, and D. H. Blackwell :
“The theory of value and the science of decision: A summary ,”
J. Operations Res. Soc. Amer.
1 : 3
(May 1953 ),
pp. 103–113 .
MR
0053466
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0053466m,
AUTHOR = {Smith, Jr., Nicholas M. and Walters,
Stanley S. and Brooks, Franklin C. and
Blackwell, David H.},
TITLE = {The theory of value and the science
of decision: {A} summary},
JOURNAL = {J. Operations Res. Soc. Amer.},
FJOURNAL = {Operational Research Society Journal},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {3},
MONTH = {May},
YEAR = {1953},
PAGES = {103--113},
URL = {http://www.jstor.org/stable/166628},
NOTE = {MR:0053466.},
ISSN = {0160-5682},
}
[22] D. Blackwell :
“A representation problem ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
5 : 2
(1954 ),
pp. 283–287 .
MR
0061653
Zbl
0055.28804
article
Abstract
BibTeX
The problem solved in this paper is the following. For a fixed number \( a \) , \( 0 < a < 1 \) , what functions \( f(x) \) on \( 0 \leq x \leq 1 \) have a representation
\begin{equation*}\tag{1} f(x) = \sum_1^{\infty}c_n\varphi_n(x), \end{equation*}
where \( c_n\geq 0 \) , \( \sum_1^{\infty}c_n \) converges, and each \( \varphi_n \) is the characteristic function of a subset of \( 0\leq x \leq 1 \) of Lebesgue measure \( a \) ? Clearly any \( f \) satisfying (1) satisfies
\begin{equation*}\tag{2} 0\leq f(x)\leq\frac{1}{a}\int_0^1 f(x)\,dx \quad\text{for all }x, \end{equation*}
since
\[ f(x)\leq\sum_1^{\infty}c_n=\frac{1}{a}\int_0^1 f(x)\,dx .\]
The result of this paper is that (2) is sufficient as well as necessary for a function \( f \) to admit a representation (1).
@article {key0061653m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {A representation problem},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {5},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1954},
PAGES = {283--287},
DOI = {10.2307/2032235},
NOTE = {MR:0061653. Zbl:0055.28804.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
}
[23] D. Blackwell and M. A. Girshick :
Theory of games and statistical decisions .
John Wiley and Sons (New York ),
1954 .
Republished by Dover in 1979 .
MR
0070134
Zbl
0056.36303
book
People
BibTeX
@book {key0070134m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Girshick, M. A.},
TITLE = {Theory of games and statistical decisions},
PUBLISHER = {John Wiley and Sons},
ADDRESS = {New York},
YEAR = {1954},
PAGES = {xi+355},
NOTE = {Republished by Dover in 1979. MR:0070134.
Zbl:0056.36303.},
}
[24] D. Blackwell :
“On optimal systems ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
25
(1954 ),
pp. 394–397 .
MR
0061776
Zbl
0055.37002
article
Abstract
BibTeX
For any sequence \( x_1, x_2, \dots \) of chance variables satisfying \( | x_n | \leq 1 \) and
\[ E(x_n\mid x_1, \dots, x_{n-1}) \leq -u(\max | x_n| \mid x_1, \dots, x_{n-1}) ,\]
where \( u \) is a fixed constant, \( 0 < u < 1 \) , and for any positive number \( t \) ,
\[ \mathrm{Pr} \bigl\{ \sup_n (x_1 + \dots + x_n) \geq t\bigr\} \leq \Bigl(\frac{1 - u}{1 + u}\Bigr)^t. \]
Equality holds for integral \( t \) when \( x_1 \) , \( x_2, \dots \) are independent with
\begin{align*} \mathrm{Pr} \{x_n = 1\} &= (1 - u)/2,\\ \mathrm{Pr} \{x_n = -1\} &= (1 + u)/2 . \end{align*}
This has a simple interpretation in terms of gambling systems, and yields a new proof of Levy’s extension of the strong law of large numbers to dependent variables, with an improved estimate for the rate of convergence.
@article {key0061776m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On optimal systems},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {25},
YEAR = {1954},
PAGES = {394--397},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177728798},
NOTE = {MR:0061776. Zbl:0055.37002.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[25] D. Blackwell :
“On multi-component attrition games ,”
Naval Res. Logist. Quart.
1 : 3
(1954 ),
pp. 210–216 .
MR
0068195
article
Abstract
BibTeX
A model is described for military games consisting of a large number of identical successive engagements, without resupply, with a player being defeated when his supply of any resource is exhausted. A method is given for determining which player should win.
@article {key0068195m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On multi-component attrition games},
JOURNAL = {Naval Res. Logist. Quart.},
FJOURNAL = {Naval Research Logistics Quarterly},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1954},
PAGES = {210--216},
DOI = {10.1002/nav.3800010308},
NOTE = {MR:0068195.},
ISSN = {0028-1441},
}
[26] D. Blackwell :
“On transient Markov processes with a countable number of states and stationary transition probabilities ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
26 : 4
(1955 ),
pp. 654–658 .
MR
0075479
Zbl
0066.11303
article
Abstract
BibTeX
We consider a Markov process \( x_0, x_1, \dots \) with a countable set \( S \) of states and stationary transition probabilities
\[ p(t \mid s) = P\{x_{n+1} = t \mid x_n = s\} .\]
Call a set \( C \) of states almost closed if
\( P\{x_n \in C\text{ for an infinite number of } n\} > 0 \) and
\( x_n \in C \) infinitely often, implies \( x_n \in C \) for all sufficiently large \( n \) , with probability one.
It is shown that there is a set \( (C_1 \) , \( C_2, \dots) \) essentially unique, of disjoint almost closed sets such that
all except at most one of the \( C_i \) are atomic, that is, \( C_i \) does not contain two disjoint almost closed subsets,
the non-atomic \( C_i \) , if present, contains no atomic subsets,
the process is certain to enter and remain in some set \( C_i \) .
A relation between the sets \( C_i \) and the bounded solutions of the system of equations
\begin{equation*}\tag{1} \alpha(s) = \sum_t \alpha(t)\,p(t \mid s) \end{equation*}
is obtained; in particular there is only one atomic \( C_i \) and no non-atomic \( C_i \) if and only if the only bounded solution of (1) is \( \alpha(t) \) = constant. This condition is shown to hold if the process is the sum of independent identical (numerical or vector) variables; whence, for such a process, the probability of entering a set \( J \) infinitely often is zero or one. The results are new only if the process has transient components. The main tool is the martingale convergence theorem.
@article {key0075479m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On transient {M}arkov processes with
a countable number of states and stationary
transition probabilities},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {26},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1955},
PAGES = {654--658},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177728425},
NOTE = {MR:0075479. Zbl:0066.11303.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[27] D. Blackwell and A. H. Bowker :
“Meyer Abraham Girshick 1908–1955 ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
26 : 3
(1955 ),
pp. 365–367 .
MR
0070573
Zbl
0065.24507
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0070573m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Bowker, Albert
H.},
TITLE = {Meyer {A}braham {G}irshick 1908--1955},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {26},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1955},
PAGES = {365--367},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177728484},
NOTE = {MR:0070573. Zbl:0065.24507.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[28] D. Blackwell :
“Controlled random walks ,”
pp. 336–338
in
Proceedings of the International Congress of Mathematicians
(Amsterdam, 2 September–9 September 1954 ),
vol. III .
Wiskundig Genootschap .
E. P. Noordhoff (Groningen ),
1956 .
MR
0085141
Zbl
0073.13204
incollection
BibTeX
@incollection {key0085141m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Controlled random walks},
BOOKTITLE = {Proceedings of the {I}nternational {C}ongress
of {M}athematicians},
VOLUME = {III},
ORGANIZATION = {Wiskundig Genootschap},
PUBLISHER = {E. P. Noordhoff},
ADDRESS = {Groningen},
YEAR = {1956},
PAGES = {336--338},
NOTE = {(Amsterdam, 2 September--9 September
1954). MR:0085141. Zbl:0073.13204.},
}
[29] D. Blackwell :
“On a class of probability spaces ,”
pp. 1–6
in
Proceedings of the third Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability
(Berkeley, CA, 26–31 December 1954 and July–August 1955 ),
vol. II .
Edited by J. Neyman .
University of California Press (Berkeley and Los Angeles ),
1956 .
MR
0084882
Zbl
0073.12301
inproceedings
People
BibTeX
@inproceedings {key0084882m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On a class of probability spaces},
BOOKTITLE = {Proceedings of the third {B}erkeley
symposium on mathematical statistics
and probability},
EDITOR = {Neyman, Jerzy},
VOLUME = {II},
PUBLISHER = {University of California Press},
ADDRESS = {Berkeley and Los Angeles},
YEAR = {1956},
PAGES = {1--6},
URL = {http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.bsmsp/1200502002},
NOTE = {(Berkeley, CA, 26--31 December 1954
and July--August 1955). MR:0084882.
Zbl:0073.12301.},
}
[30] D. Blackwell :
“An analog of the minimax theorem for vector payoffs ,”
Pacific J. Math.
6 : 1
(1956 ),
pp. 1–8 .
MR
0081804
Zbl
0074.34403
article
BibTeX
@article {key0081804m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {An analog of the minimax theorem for
vector payoffs},
JOURNAL = {Pacific J. Math.},
FJOURNAL = {Pacific Journal of Mathematics},
VOLUME = {6},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1956},
PAGES = {1--8},
URL = {http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.pjm/1103044235},
NOTE = {MR:0081804. Zbl:0074.34403.},
ISSN = {0030-8730},
}
[31] D. Blackwell :
“The entropy of functions of finite-state Markov chains ,”
pp. 13–20
in
Information theory, statistical decision functions, random processes
(Liblice, Czech Republic, 28 November–30 November 1956 ),
vol. 1 .
Edited by J. Kožešnik .
Czechoslovak Academy of Sciences (Prague ),
1957 .
MR
0100297
Zbl
0085.12401
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0100297m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The entropy of functions of finite-state
{M}arkov chains},
BOOKTITLE = {Information theory, statistical decision
functions, random processes},
EDITOR = {Ko\v{z}e\v{s}nik, Jaroslav},
VOLUME = {1},
PUBLISHER = {Czechoslovak Academy of Sciences},
ADDRESS = {Prague},
YEAR = {1957},
PAGES = {13--20},
NOTE = {(Liblice, Czech Republic, 28 November--30
November 1956). MR:0100297. Zbl:0085.12401.},
}
[32] D. Blackwell and J. L. Hodges, Jr. :
“Design for the control of selection bias ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
28 : 2
(1957 ),
pp. 449–460 .
MR
0088849
Zbl
0081.36403
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Suppose an experimenter \( E \) wishes to compare the effectiveness of two treatments, \( A \) and \( B \) , on a somewhat vaguely defined population. As individuals arrive, \( E \) decides whether they are in the population, and if he decides that they are, he administers \( A \) or \( B \) and notes the result, until \( nA \) ’s and \( nB \) ’s have been administered. Plainly, if \( E \) is aware, before deciding whether an individual is in the population, which treatment is to be administered next, he may, not necessarily deliberately, introduce a bias into the experiment. This bias we call selection bias.
We propose to investigate the extent to which a statistician \( S \) , by determining the order in which treatments are administered, and not revealing to \( E \) which treatment comes next until after the individual who is to receive it has been selected, can control this selection bias. Thus a design \( d \) is a distribution over the set \( T \) of the \( \binom{2n}{n} \) sequences of length \( 2n \) containing \( nA \) ’s and \( nB \) ’s.
We shall measure the bias of a design by the maximum expected number of correct guesses which an experimenter can achieve, knowing \( d \) , attempting to guess the successive elements of a sequence \( t \in T \) selected by \( d \) , and being told after each guess whether or not it is correct. The distribution of the number \( G \) of correct guesses depends both on \( d \) and on the prediction method \( p \) used by the experimenter. We shall consider particularly two designs, the truncated binomial, in which the successive treatments are selected independently with probability \( 1/2 \) each until \( n \) treatments of one kind have occurred, and the sampling design, in which all \( \binom{2n}{n} \) sequences are equally likely.
We shall consider particularly two prediction methods, the convergent prediction, which predicts that treatment which has hitherto occurred less often, and the divergent prediction, which predicts that treatment which has hitherto occurred more often, except that after \( n \) treatments of one kind have been administered, the divergent prediction agrees with the convergent predictions that the other treatment will follow; when both treatments have occurred equally often, either method predicts \( A \) or \( B \) by tossing a fair coin, independently for each case of equality.
We find that among all designs, the truncated binomial minimizes the maximum expected number of correct guesses. For this design, the expected number of correct guesses is independent of the prediction method, and is
\[ n + n \binom{2n}{n} \big/ 2^{2n} \sim n + \Bigl(\frac{n}{\pi}\Bigr)^{1/2} .\]
With the truncated binomial design, the variance in the number of correct guesses is largest for the divergence strategy and is
\[ \frac{3n}{2} - D - \frac{D^2}{4} \sim \frac{(3\pi - 2)n}{2\pi} - 2\Bigl(\frac{n}{\pi}\Bigr)^{1/2}, \]
where \( D = n \binom{2n}{n} \big/ 2^{2n - 1} \) , and is smallest for the convergence strategy, and is
\[ \frac{n}{2} - \frac{D^2}{4} \sim \frac{(\pi - 1)n}{2\pi} .\]
For the sampling design, convergent prediction maximizes the expected number of correct guesses; this maximum is
\[ n + 2^{2n - 1} \!\big/ \binom{2n}{n} - \frac{1}{2} \sim n + \Bigl(\frac{\pi n}{4}\Bigr)^{1/2}. \]
Finally we note that, if treatments are selected independently at random, bias of the kind we discuss disappears, but the treatment numbers can no longer be preassigned. Three such designs are considered: the fixed total design, in which the total number of treatments is a fixed number \( s \) , the fixed factor design, in which we continue until
\[ \frac{1}{X} + \frac{1}{Y} \leq \frac{2}{n} ,\]
where \( X \) is the number of \( A \) treatments and \( Y \) is the number of \( B \) treatments administered, and the fixed minimum design, in which we continue until \( \min (X, Y) = n \) . For the fixed total design, we find that, for \( s = 2n + 4 \) ,
\[ \mathrm{Pr}\Bigl(\frac{1}{X} + \frac{1}{Y} \leq \frac{2}{n}\Bigr) \sim 0.955 \]
for large \( n \) ; at the expense of 4 extra observations, we have a bias-free design whose variance factor will with probability \( 0.955 \) be smaller than that in which treatment numbers are preassigned. For the fixed factor design, the additional number of observations required to achieve the given precision has for large \( n \) the distribution of the square of a normal deviate. For the fixed minimum design, in which we guarantee precision for the estimated effect of each treatment, the expected number of additional observations is roughly \( 1.13 (n)^{1/2} \) .
@article {key0088849m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Hodges, Jr., J.
L.},
TITLE = {Design for the control of selection
bias},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {28},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1957},
PAGES = {449--460},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706973},
NOTE = {MR:0088849. Zbl:0081.36403.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[33] D. Blackwell and L. Koopmans :
“On the identifiability problem for functions of finite Markov chains ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
28 : 4
(1957 ),
pp. 1011–1015 .
MR
0099081
Zbl
0080.34901
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( M = \| m_{ij} \| \) be a \( 4{\times}4 \) irreducible aperiodic Markov matrix such that \( h_1 \neq h_2 \) , \( h_3 \neq h_4 \) , where \( h_i = m_{i1} + m_{i2} \) . Let \( x_1 \) , \( x_2, \dots \) be a stationary Markov process with transition matrix \( M \) , and let \( y_n = 0 \) when \( x_n = 1 \) or 2, \( y_n = 1 \) when \( x_n = 3 \) or 4. For any finite sequence
\[ s = (\varepsilon_1 \( , \) \varepsilon_2, \dots\( , \) \varepsilon_n) \]
of 0s and 1s, let
\[ p(s) = \mathrm{Pr}\{y_1 = \varepsilon_1, \dots, y_n = \varepsilon_n\} .\]
If
\begin{equation*}\tag{1} p^2(00) \neq p(0)\,p(000) \quad\text{and}\quad p^2(01) \neq p(1)\,p(010), \end{equation*}
the joint distribution of \( y_1 \) , \( y_2, \dots \) is uniquely determined by the eight probabilities \( p(0) \) , \( p(00) \) , \( p(000) \) , \( p(010) \) , \( p(0000) \) , \( p(0010) \) , \( p(0100) \) , \( p(0110) \) , so that two matrices \( M \) determine the same joint distribution of \( y_1 \) , \( y_2, \dots \) whenever the eight probabilities listed agree, provided (1) is satisfied. The method consists in showing that the function \( p \) satisfies the recurrence relation
\[ p(s, \varepsilon, \delta, 0) = p(s, \varepsilon, 0)\,a(\varepsilon, \delta) + p(s, \varepsilon)\,b(\varepsilon, \delta) \]
for all \( s \) and \( \varepsilon = 0 \) or 1, \( \delta = 0 \) or 1, where \( a(\varepsilon, \delta) \) , \( b(\varepsilon, \delta) \) are (easily computed) functions of \( M \) , and noting that, if (1) is satisfied, \( a(\varepsilon, \delta) \) and \( b(\varepsilon, \delta) \) are determined by the eight probabilities listed. The class of doubly stochastic matrices yielding the same joint distribution for \( y_1 \) , \( y_2, \dots \) is described somewhat more explicitly, and the case of a larger number of states is considered briefly.
@article {key0099081m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Koopmans, Lambert},
TITLE = {On the identifiability problem for functions
of finite {M}arkov chains},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {28},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1957},
PAGES = {1011--1015},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706802},
NOTE = {MR:0099081. Zbl:0080.34901.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[34] D. Blackwell :
“On discrete variables whose sum is absolutely continuous ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
28 : 2
(1957 ),
pp. 520–521 .
MR
0088091
Zbl
0078.31602
article
Abstract
BibTeX
If \( \{Z_n\} \) , \( n = 1, 2, \ldots \) is a stationary stochastic process with \( D \) states
\[ 0, 1, \dots, D - 1 \quad\text{and}\quad X = \sum^\infty_1 \frac{Z_k}{D^n} ,\]
Harris [1955] has shown that the distribution of \( X \) is absolutely continuous if and only if the \( Z_n \) are independent and uniformly distributed over \( {}0 \) , \( 1, \dots \) , \( D - 1 \) , i.e., if and only if the distribution of \( X \) is uniform on the unit interval. In this note we show that if \( \{Z_n\} \) , \( n = 1 \) , \( 2, \dots \) is any stochastic process with \( D \) states \( {}0 \) , \( 1, \dots \) , \( D - 1 \) such that
\[ X = \sum^\infty_1 \frac{Z_n}{D^n} \]
has an absolutely continuous distribution, then the conditional distribution of
\[ R_k = \sum^\infty_{n = 1} \frac{Z_{k + n}}{D^n} \]
given \( Z_1, \dots \) , \( Z_k \) converges to the uniform distribution on the unit interval with probability 1 as \( k \to \infty \) . It follows that the unconditional distribution of \( R_k \) converges to the uniform distribution as \( k \to \infty \) . Since if \( \{Z_n\} \) is stationary the distribution of \( R_k \) is independent of \( k \) , the result of Harris follows.
@article {key0088091m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On discrete variables whose sum is absolutely
continuous},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {28},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1957},
PAGES = {520--521},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706985},
NOTE = {MR:0088091. Zbl:0078.31602.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[35] D. Blackwell, L. Breiman, and A. J. Thomasian :
“Proof of Shannon’s transmission theorem for finite-state indecomposable channels ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
29 : 4
(1958 ),
pp. 1209–1220 .
MR
0118570
Zbl
0096.10901
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
For finite-state indecomposable channels, Shannon’s basic theorem, that transmission is possible at any rate less than channel capacity but not at any greater rate, is proved. A necessary and sufficient condition for indecomposability, from which it follows that every channel with finite memory is indecomposable, is given. An important tool is a modification, for some processes which are not quite stationary, of theorems of McMillan and Breiman on probabilities of long sequences in ergodic processes.
@article {key0118570m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Breiman, Leo and
Thomasian, A. J.},
TITLE = {Proof of {S}hannon's transmission theorem
for finite-state indecomposable channels},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {29},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1958},
PAGES = {1209--1220},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706452},
NOTE = {MR:0118570. Zbl:0096.10901.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[36] D. Blackwell :
“Another countable Markov process with only instantaneous states ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
29 : 1
(1958 ),
pp. 313–316 .
MR
0093822
Zbl
0085.12702
article
BibTeX
@article {key0093822m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Another countable {M}arkov process with
only instantaneous states},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {29},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1958},
PAGES = {313--316},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706735},
NOTE = {MR:0093822. Zbl:0085.12702.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[37] D. Blackwell and J. L. Hodges, Jr. :
“The probability in the extreme tail of a convolution ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
30 : 4
(1959 ),
pp. 1113–1120 .
MR
0112197
Zbl
0099.35105
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( X_1, X_2, \dots \) be independent and identically distributed random variables with possible values that are integers whose differences have g.c.d. one. Assume the m.g.f. of \( X_1 \) exists in an interval about 0, let \( a \) be any number such that
\[ E(X_1) < a < \sup X_1 ,\]
and let
\[ \varphi(a, t) = E\,e^{t(X_{1-a})} .\]
There exists a unique value \( t^{\ast}(a) \) of \( t \) which minimizes \( \varphi(a, t) \) with respect to \( t \) ; write
\[ m(a) = \varphi[ a, t^{\ast}(a)] \quad\text{and}\quad z = e^{-t^{\ast}(a)} .\]
Let \( Y_1,Y_2, \dots \) be independent and identically distributed random variables such that \( Y_1 \) and \( X_1 \) have the same range and
\[ \Pr(Y_1 = x) = \Pr(X_1 = x) \cdot \frac{e^{t^{\ast}(a)\,(x-a)}}{m(a)} ,\]
and let \( \mu_2 = \sigma^2, \mu_3, \mu_4 \) be central moments of \( Y_1 \) . We show that
\[ \Pr \{X_1 + \dots + X_n = na\} = [ m(a) ]^n \Pr \{Y_1 + \dots + Y_n = na\} ,\]
and use this to establish the approximation
\[ \Pr \{X_1 + \dots + X_n = na\} = \pi^{\ast\ast}_n[ 1 + 0(n^{-2})] ,\]
where \( na \) is a possible value of \( X_1 + \dots + X_n \) and
\[ \pi^{\ast\ast}_n = \frac{[ m(a)]^n}{\sigma\sqrt{2\pi n}} \Bigl[ 1 + \frac{1}{8n} \Bigl(\frac{\mu_4}{\mu^2_2} - 3 - \frac{5}{3} \frac{\mu^3_2}{\mu^3_2}\Bigr)\Bigr]. \]
Similarly we find that
\[ \Pr \{X_1 + \dots + X_n \geq na\} = \Pi^{\ast\ast}_n[ 1 + 0(n^{-2})] ,\]
where
\[ \Pi^{\ast\ast}_n = \pi^{\ast\ast}_n \cdot \frac{1}{1 - z}\Bigl\{1 - \frac{1}{2n}\Bigl[\frac{(z\mu_3/\mu_2) + z(1 + z)/(1 - z)}{(1 + z)\mu_2}\Bigr]\Bigr\}. \]
We provide some numerical illustrations of the accuracy of these approximations, and give a conjectured analog of the leading term of \( \Pi^{\ast\ast}_n \) for nonlattice variables.
@article {key0112197m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Hodges, Jr., J.
L.},
TITLE = {The probability in the extreme tail
of a convolution},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {30},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1959},
PAGES = {1113--1120},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706094},
NOTE = {MR:0112197. Zbl:0099.35105.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[38] D. Blackwell :
“Infinite codes for memoryless channels ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
30 : 4
(1959 ),
pp. 1242–1244 .
MR
0127448
Zbl
0104.11701
article
Abstract
BibTeX
For any finite set \( S \) , we denote by \( S^{(N)} \) the set of all sequences \( (s_1, \dots \) , \( s_N) \) , where \( s_n \in S \) for \( n = 1 \) , \( 2, \dots \) , \( N \) . For a memoryless channel with finite input alphabet \( A \) , finite output alphabet \( B \) , an infinite code (for transmitting at rate 1) is defined as consisting of
a sequence \( \{f_n\} \) of functions, where \( f_n \) maps \( I^{(n)} \) into \( A \) , and \( I \) consists of the two elements 0 and 1,
a nondecreasing sequence \( \{M(n)\} \) of positive integers such that \( M(n)/n \to 1 \) as \( n \to \infty \) , and
a sequence \( \{g_n\} \) of functions, where \( \{g_n\} \) maps \( B^{(n)} \) into \( I^{(M(n))} \) .
An infinite sequence \( x = (x_1 \) , \( x_2, \dots) \) of 0s and 1s, together with an infinite code, defines a sequence of independent output variables \( y_1 \) , \( y_2, \dots \) , with
\[ \Pr \{y_n = b\} = p\bigl(b \mid f_n(x_1, \dots, x_n)\bigr), \]
where \( p(b \mid a) \) is the probability that the output symbol of the channel is \( b \) , given that the corresponding input symbol is \( a \) , and defines a sequence of estimated messages \( t_1 \) , \( t_2, \dots \) , where
\[ t_n = g_n(y_1, \dots \( , \) y_n) .\]
We shall say that the code is effective at \( x \) if, with probability 1,
\[ t_n = (x_1, \dots,x_{M(n)}) \]
for all sufficiently large \( n \) , and shall say that the code is effective if it is effective for every \( x \) . The result of this note is the
For any memoryless channel with capacity \( C > 1 \) , there is an effective code.
@article {key0127448m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Infinite codes for memoryless channels},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {30},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1959},
PAGES = {1242--1244},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706107},
NOTE = {MR:0127448. Zbl:0104.11701.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[39] D. Blackwell, L. Breiman, and A. J. Thomasian :
“The capacity of a class of channels ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
30 : 4
(1959 ),
pp. 1229–1241 .
MR
0127449
Zbl
0104.11604
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key0127449m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Breiman, Leo and
Thomasian, A. J.},
TITLE = {The capacity of a class of channels},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {30},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1959},
PAGES = {1229--1241},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177706106},
NOTE = {MR:0127449. Zbl:0104.11604.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[40] D. Blackwell, L. Breiman, and A. J. Thomasian :
“The capacities of certain channel classes under random coding ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
31 : 3
(1960 ),
pp. 558–567 .
MR
0127450
Zbl
0119.13805
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0127450m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Breiman, Leo and
Thomasian, A. J.},
TITLE = {The capacities of certain channel classes
under random coding},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {31},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1960},
PAGES = {558--567},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177705783},
NOTE = {MR:0127450. Zbl:0119.13805.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[41] C. B. Bell, D. Blackwell, and L. Breiman :
“On the completeness of order statistics ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
31 : 3
(1960 ),
pp. 794–797 .
MR
0116427
Zbl
0101.12201
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( X_1, X_2, \dots, X_n \) be a sample of a one-dimensional random variable \( X \) ; let the order statistic \( T(X_1 \) , \( X_2, \dots \) , \( X_n) \) be defined in such a manner that
\[ T(x_1, x_2, \dots, x_n) = (x^{(1)}, x^{(2)}, \dots, x^{(n)}) \]
where \( x^{(1)} \leq x^{(2)} \leq \dots \leq x^{(n)} \) denote the ordered \( x \) ’s; and let \( \Omega \) be a class of one-dimensional cpf’s, i.e., cumulative probability functions. The order statistic, \( T \) , is said to be a complete statistic with respect to the class
\[ \{P^{(n)} \mid P \in \Omega\} \]
of \( n \) -fold power probability distributions if
\[ E_p^{(n)}\bigl\{h[ T(X_1, \dots, X_n)]\bigr\} = 0 \]
for all \( P \in \Omega \) implies
\[ h[ T(x_1, \dots, x_n)] = 0 \quad\text{a.e. }P^{(n)} ,\]
for all \( F \in \Omega \) . The class \( \Omega \) is said to be symmetrically complete whenever the latter condition holds. Since the completeness of the order statistic plays an essential role in nonparametric estimation and hypothesis testing, e.g., Fraser [1954] and Bell [1960], it is of interest to determine those classes of cpf’s for which the order statistic is complete. Many of the traditionally studied classes of cpf’s on the real line are known to be symmetrically complete, e.g., all continuous cpf’s [Lehmann 1959, pp. 131–134, 152–153]; all cpf’s absolutely continuous with respect to Lebesgue measure [Fraser 1957, pp. 23–31]; and all exponentials of a certain form [Lehmann 1959, pp. 131–134]. The object of this note is to present a different [Lehmann 1959, pp. 131–134, 152–153] demonstration of the symmetric completeness of the class of all continuous cpf’s; and to extend this and other known completeness results to probability spaces other than the real line, e.g., Fraser [1954], and Lehmann and Scheffé [1950; 1955].
@article {key0116427m,
AUTHOR = {Bell, C. B. and Blackwell, David and
Breiman, Leo},
TITLE = {On the completeness of order statistics},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {31},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1960},
PAGES = {794--797},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177705808},
NOTE = {MR:0116427. Zbl:0101.12201.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[42] D. Blackwell :
“Minimax and irreducible matrices ,”
J. Math. Anal. Appl.
3 : 1
(August 1961 ),
pp. 37–39 .
MR
0139495
Zbl
0111.33404
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Call an \( n{\times}n \) matrix \( A = \|A(i,j)\| \) with nonnegative elements irreducible if for every \( i,j \) there is an \( N \) for which \( A^{(N)}(i,j) > 0 \) , where
\[ A^{(N)} = \|A^{(N)}(i,j)\| \]
is the \( N \) -th power of \( A \) . A useful result of Frobenius [Karlin 1959] is: Every irreducible \( A \) has a positive eigenvalue \( \lambda_0 \) which is at least as large as the absolute value of any other eigenvalue. This eigenvalue is simple and its eigenvector has all coordinates strictly of the same sign.
We shall obtain this result from the minimax theorem of game theory. Our main result is the
If \( A \) is irreducible, there is exactly one number \( \lambda_0 \) for which the value of the game with matrix \( A - \lambda_0 I \) is zero (\( I \) is the \( n{\times}n \) identity matrix). \( \lambda_0 > 0 \) . Each player has a unique good strategy, and all coordinates of each player’s good strategy are positive.
We shall see that this \( \lambda_0 \) is the \( \lambda_0 \) of Frobenius’ result, and that the strategy vectors are the left, right eigenvectors for \( \lambda_0 \) .
@article {key0139495m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Minimax and irreducible matrices},
JOURNAL = {J. Math. Anal. Appl.},
FJOURNAL = {Journal of Mathematical Analysis and
Applications},
VOLUME = {3},
NUMBER = {1},
MONTH = {August},
YEAR = {1961},
PAGES = {37--39},
DOI = {10.1016/0022-247X(61)90005-1},
NOTE = {MR:0139495. Zbl:0111.33404.},
ISSN = {0022-247x},
}
[43] D. Blackwell :
“Exponential error bounds for finite state channels ,”
pp. 57–63
in
Proceedings of the fourth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statistics and probability
(Berkeley, CA, 20 June–30 July 1960 ),
vol. I .
Edited by J. Neyman .
University of California Press (Berkeley and Los Angeles ),
1961 .
MR
0135199
Zbl
0104.11603
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0135199m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Exponential error bounds for finite
state channels},
BOOKTITLE = {Proceedings of the fourth {B}erkeley
symposium on mathematical statistics
and probability},
EDITOR = {Neyman, Jerzy},
VOLUME = {I},
PUBLISHER = {University of California Press},
ADDRESS = {Berkeley and Los Angeles},
YEAR = {1961},
PAGES = {57--63},
NOTE = {(Berkeley, CA, 20 June--30 July 1960).
MR:0135199. Zbl:0104.11603.},
}
[44] D. Blackwell :
“Information theory ,”
pp. 182–193
in
Modern mathematics for the engineer .
Edited by E. F. Beckenbach .
McGraw-Hill (New York ),
1961 .
MR
0129161
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0129161m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Information theory},
BOOKTITLE = {Modern mathematics for the engineer},
EDITOR = {Beckenbach, Edwin F.},
PUBLISHER = {McGraw-Hill},
ADDRESS = {New York},
YEAR = {1961},
PAGES = {182--193},
NOTE = {MR:0129161.},
}
[45] D. Blackwell :
“On the functional equation of dynamic programming ,”
J. Math. Anal. Appl.
2 : 2
(April 1961 ),
pp. 273–276 .
MR
0126090
Zbl
0096.35503
article
BibTeX
@article {key0126090m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On the functional equation of dynamic
programming},
JOURNAL = {J. Math. Anal. Appl.},
FJOURNAL = {Journal of Mathematical Analysis and
Applications},
VOLUME = {2},
NUMBER = {2},
MONTH = {April},
YEAR = {1961},
PAGES = {273--276},
DOI = {10.1016/0022-247X(61)90035-X},
NOTE = {MR:0126090. Zbl:0096.35503.},
ISSN = {0022-247x},
}
[46] D. Blackwell and L. Dubins :
“Merging of opinions with increasing information ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
33 : 3
(1962 ),
pp. 882–886 .
MR
0149577
Zbl
0109.35704
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
One of us [Blackwell 1957] has shown that if \( Z_n \) , \( n = 1 \) , \( 2,\dots \) is a stochastic process with \( D \) states, \( {}0 \) , \( 1,\dots \) , \( D-1 \) such that
\[ X=\sum_{n=1}^{\infty} \frac{Z_n}{D^n} \]
has an absolutely continuous distribution with respect to Lebesgue measure, then the conditional distribution of
\[ R_k = \sum_{n=1}^{\infty} \frac{Z_{k+n}}{D^n} \]
given \( Z_1,\dots \) , \( Z_k \) converges with probability one as \( k\to\infty \) to the uniform distribution on the unit interval, in the sense that for each \( \lambda \) , \( 0 < \lambda \leq 1 \) ,
\[ P(R_k < \lambda\mid Z_1,\dots,Z_k)\to \lambda \]
with probability 1 as \( k\to \infty \) . It follows that the unconditional distribution of \( R_k \) converges to the uniform distribution as \( k\to\infty \) . If \( \{Z_n\} \) is stationary, the distribution of \( R_k \) is independent of \( k \) , and hence uniform, a result obtained earlier by Harris [1955]. Earlier work relevant to convergence of opinion can be found in [Savage, 1954, chap. 3, sect. 6].
Here we generalize these results and also show that the conditional distribution of \( R_k \) given \( Z_1,\dots \) , \( Z_k \) converges in a much stronger sense. All probabilities in this paper are countably additive.
@article {key0149577m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester},
TITLE = {Merging of opinions with increasing
information},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {33},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1962},
PAGES = {882--886},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177704456},
NOTE = {MR:0149577. Zbl:0109.35704.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[47] D. Blackwell :
“Discrete dynamic programming ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
33 : 2
(1962 ),
pp. 719–726 .
MR
0149965
Zbl
0133.12906
article
Abstract
BibTeX
We consider a system with a finite number \( S \) of states \( s \) , labeled by the integers \( {}1 \) , \( 2, \dots \) , \( S \) . Periodically, say once a day, we observe the current state of the system, and then choose an action \( a \) from a finite set \( A \) of possible actions. As a joint result of the current state \( s \) and the chosen action \( a \) , two things happen:
we receive an immediate income \( i(s,a) \) and
the system moves to a new state \( s^{\prime} \) with the probability of a particular new state \( s^{\prime} \) given by a function \( q = q(s^{\prime}\mid s,a) \) .
Finally there is specified a discount factor \( \beta \) , \( 0 \leq \beta < 1 \) , so that the value of unit income \( n \) days in the future is \( \beta^n \) . Our problem is to choose a policy which maximizes our total expected income. This problem, which is an interesting special case of the general dynamic programming problem, has been solved by Howard in his excellent book [Howard 1960]. The case \( \beta = 1 \) , also studied by Howard, is substantially more difficult. We shall obtain in this case results slightly beyond those of Howard, though still not complete. Our method, which treats \( \beta = 1 \) as a limiting case of \( \beta < 1 \) , seems rather simpler than Howard’s.
@article {key0149965m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Discrete dynamic programming},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {33},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1962},
PAGES = {719--726},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177704593},
NOTE = {MR:0149965. Zbl:0133.12906.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[48] D. Blackwell and C. Ryll-Nardzewski :
“Non-existence of everywhere proper conditional distributions ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
34 : 1
(1963 ),
pp. 223–225 .
MR
0148097
Zbl
0122.13202
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0148097m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Ryll-Nardzewski, C.},
TITLE = {Non-existence of everywhere proper conditional
distributions},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {34},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1963},
PAGES = {223--225},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177704259},
NOTE = {MR:0148097. Zbl:0122.13202.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[49] D. Blackwell and L. E. Dubins :
“A converse to the dominated convergence theorem ,”
Illinois J. Math.
7 : 3
(1963 ),
pp. 508–514 .
MR
0151572
Zbl
0146.37503
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
On a probability space \( (\Omega, \mathcal{B}, P) \) , let \( \{f_n \) , \( n=1 \) , \( 2,\dots\} \) be a sequence of nonnegative random variables in \( L_1 \) such that \( f_n \to f\in L_1 \) with probability 1 and define \( g=\sup_n f_n \) . If \( g\in L_1 \) , the Lebesgue dominated convergence theorem asserts that \( E(f_n)\to E(f) \) . More generally, as noted by [Doob 1953, p. 23], if \( g\in L_1 \) , then for any Borel field \( \mathcal{B}_0 \) contained in \( \mathcal{B} \) ,
\[ E(f_n\mid\mathcal{B}_0) \to E(f\mid\mathcal{B}_0) \quad\text{a.e.} \]
If one extends this result in a minor manner, Lebesgue’s condition \( g\in L_1 \) is not only sufficient but necessary, as the following converse to the dominated convergence theorem asserts.
If \( f_n \geq 0 \) , \( f_n \to f \) a.e., \( f_n\in L_1 \) , and \( g = \sup_n f_n \notin L_1 \) , there are, on a suitable probability space, random variables \( \{f_n^* \) , \( n=1 \) , \( 2,\dots\} \) , \( f^* \) , and a Borel field \( \mathcal{C} \) such that \( f^* \) , \( f_1^* \) , \( f_2^*,\dots \) have the same joint distribution as \( f \) , \( f_1 \) , \( f_2,\dots \) , and
\[ P\bigl\{E(f_n^*\mid\mathcal{C})\to E(f^*\mid\mathcal{C})\bigr\} = 0. \]
@article {key0151572m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester
E.},
TITLE = {A converse to the dominated convergence
theorem},
JOURNAL = {Illinois J. Math.},
FJOURNAL = {Illinois Journal of Mathematics},
VOLUME = {7},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1963},
PAGES = {508--514},
URL = {http://projecteuclid.org/euclid.ijm/1255644957},
NOTE = {MR:0151572. Zbl:0146.37503.},
ISSN = {0019-2082},
}
[50] D. Blackwell and L. E. Dubins :
“Sharp bounds on the distribution of the Hardy–Littlewood maximal function ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
14 : 3
(1963 ),
pp. 450–453 .
MR
0148842
Zbl
0118.05401
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Somewhat tangentially to a recent study [Blackwell and Dubins 1963], we happened to notice an inequality which supplements one of Hardy and Littlewood [1930, Theorem 7, p. 95].
@article {key0148842m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester
E.},
TITLE = {Sharp bounds on the distribution of
the {H}ardy--{L}ittlewood maximal function},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {14},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1963},
PAGES = {450--453},
DOI = {10.2307/2033819},
NOTE = {MR:0148842. Zbl:0118.05401.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
}
[51] D. Blackwell :
“Memoryless strategies in finite-stage dynamic programming ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
35 : 3
(1964 ),
pp. 863–865 .
MR
0162642
Zbl
0127.36406
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Given three sets \( X \) , \( Y \) , \( A \) and a bounded function \( u \) on \( Y \times A \) , suppose that we are to observe a point \( (x,y)\in X\times Y \) and then select any point \( a \) we please from \( A \) , after which we receive an income \( u(y,a) \) . In trying to maximize our income, is there any point to letting our choice of \( a \) depend on \( x \) as well as on \( y \) ? We shall give a formalization to this question in which sometimes there is a point. If \( (x,y) \) is selected according to a known distribution \( Q \) , however, we show that dependence on \( x \) is pointless, and apply the result to obtain memoryless strategies in finite-state dynamic programming problems.
@article {key0162642m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Memoryless strategies in finite-stage
dynamic programming},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {35},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {863--865},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177703586},
NOTE = {MR:0162642. Zbl:0127.36406.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[52] D. Blackwell :
“Probability bounds via dynamic programming ,”
pp. 277–280
in
Stochastic processes in mathematical physics and engineering
(New York, 30 April–2 May 1963 ).
Edited by R. E. Bellman .
Proceedings of Symposia in Applied Mathematics XVI .
American Mathematical Society (Providence, RI ),
1964 .
MR
0163347
Zbl
0139.13804
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0163347m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Probability bounds via dynamic programming},
BOOKTITLE = {Stochastic processes in mathematical
physics and engineering},
EDITOR = {Bellman, Richard Ernest},
SERIES = {Proceedings of Symposia in Applied Mathematics},
NUMBER = {XVI},
PUBLISHER = {American Mathematical Society},
ADDRESS = {Providence, RI},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {277--280},
NOTE = {(New York, 30 April--2 May 1963). MR:0163347.
Zbl:0139.13804.},
ISBN = {9780821813164},
}
[53] D. Blackwell and D. Freedman :
“The tail \( \sigma \) -field of a Markov chain and a theorem of Orey ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
35 : 3
(1964 ),
pp. 1291–1295 .
MR
0164375
Zbl
0127.35204
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Orey [1962] proved that, if \( p \) is a transition probability matrix with one ergodic class of recurrent and aperiodic states, then
\[ \lim_{n\to\infty}\sum_j|p^n(i_1,j) - p^n(i_2,j)| = 0 .\]
We present here a somewhat different proof which may give additional insight. Of course, Orey’s result implies the corollary to our Theorem 2, as well as our Theorem 1 and its corollaries.
@article {key0164375m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Freedman, David},
TITLE = {The tail \$\sigma \$-field of a {M}arkov
chain and a theorem of {O}rey},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {35},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {1291--1295},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177703284},
NOTE = {MR:0164375. Zbl:0127.35204.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[54] D. Blackwell and D. Freedman :
“A remark on the coin tossing game ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
35 : 3
(1964 ),
pp. 1345–1347 .
MR
0169257
Zbl
0129.31502
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( X_n:n\geq 1 \) be independent and identically distributed random variables, assuming the values \( \pm 1 \) with probability \( 1/2 \) each. Let
\[ S_n = X_1 + \dots + X_n .\]
If \( 0 < c < \infty \) , DeMoivre’s (1718) central limit theorem implies \( |S_n| > cn^{1/2} \) for a large enough \( n \) . How large? Let \( \tau(N,c) \) be the least \( n\geq N \) with \( |S_n| > cn^{1/2} \) .
The mean waiting time for \( |S_n| \) to exceed \( n^{1/2} \) is infinite; that is, \( E[\tau(1,1)] = \infty \) .
If \( 0 < c < 1 \) , the mean waiting time for \( |S_n| \) to exceed \( cn^{1/2} \) is finite; that is, \( E[\tau(N,c)] < \infty \) for al \( N \) .
@article {key0169257m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Freedman, David},
TITLE = {A remark on the coin tossing game},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {35},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {1345--1347},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177703292},
NOTE = {MR:0169257. Zbl:0129.31502.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[55] D. Blackwell, P. Deuel, and D. Freedman :
“The last return to equilibrium in a coin-tossing game ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
35 : 3
(1964 ),
pp. 1344 .
MR
0169256
Zbl
0129.31501
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0169256m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Deuel, P. and Freedman,
D.},
TITLE = {The last return to equilibrium in a
coin-tossing game},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {35},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {1344},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177703291},
NOTE = {MR:0169256. Zbl:0129.31501.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[56] D. Blackwell and D. Kendall :
“The Martin boundary for Pólya’s urn scheme, and an application to stochastic population growth ,”
J. Appl. Probability
1 : 2
(December 1964 ),
pp. 284–296 .
MR
0176518
Zbl
0129.10702
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
In 1923 Eggenberger and Pólya [1923] introduced the following “urn scheme” as a model for the development of a contagious phenomenon. A box contains \( b \) black and \( r \) red balls, and a ball is drawn from it at random with “double replacement” (i.e. whatever ball is drawn, it is returned to the box together with a fresh ball of the same colour ); the procedure is then continued indefinitely. A slightly more complicated version with \( m \) -fold replacement is sometimes discussed, but it will be sufficient for our purposes to keep \( m=2 \) and it will be convenient further to simplify the scheme by taking \( b = r = 1 \) as the initial condition. We shall however generalise the scheme in another direction by allowing an arbitrary number \( k \) (\( \geq 2 \) ) of colours. Thus initially the box will contain \( k \) differently coloured balls and successive random drawings will be followed by double replacement as before. We write \( s^n \) (a \( k \) -vector with \( j \) -th component \( s_j^n \) ) for the numerical composition of the box immediately after the \( n \) -th replacement, so that \( s^0 = (1 \) , \( 1,\dots \) , \( 1) \) , and we observe that \( \{s^n: \) \( n=0 \) , \( {}1 \) , \( 2,\dots\} \) is a Markov proces for which the state-space consists of all ordered \( k \) -ads of positive integers, the (constant) transition-probability matrix having elements determined by
\[ Pr\{s^{n+1} = s^n + e(i)\mid s^n\} = \frac{s_i^n}{S^n} ,\]
where \( S^n \) is the sum of the components of \( s^n \) and \( (e(i))_j = \delta_{ij} \) . We shall calculate the Martin boundary for this Markov process, and point out some applications to stochastic models for population growth.
@article {key0176518m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Kendall, David},
TITLE = {The {M}artin boundary for {P}\'olya's
urn scheme, and an application to stochastic
population growth},
JOURNAL = {J. Appl. Probability},
FJOURNAL = {Journal of Applied Probability},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {2},
MONTH = {December},
YEAR = {1964},
PAGES = {284--296},
URL = {http://www.jstor.org/pss/3211860},
NOTE = {MR:0176518. Zbl:0129.10702.},
ISSN = {0021-9002},
}
[57] D. Blackwell :
“Discounted dynamic programming ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
36 : 1
(1965 ),
pp. 226–235 .
MR
0173536
Zbl
0133.42805
article
BibTeX
@article {key0173536m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Discounted dynamic programming},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {36},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1965},
PAGES = {226--235},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177700285},
NOTE = {MR:0173536. Zbl:0133.42805.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[58] D. Blackwell and L. Dubins :
“An elementary proof of an identity of Gould’s ,”
Bol. Soc. Mat. Mexicana (2)
11
(1966 ),
pp. 108–110 .
MR
0233713
Zbl
0196.29001
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key0233713m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester},
TITLE = {An elementary proof of an identity of
{G}ould's},
JOURNAL = {Bol. Soc. Mat. Mexicana (2)},
FJOURNAL = {Bolet\'in de la Sociedad Matem\'atica
Mexicana, second series},
VOLUME = {11},
YEAR = {1966},
PAGES = {108--110},
NOTE = {MR:0233713. Zbl:0196.29001.},
ISSN = {1405-213X},
}
[59] P. J. Bickel and D. Blackwell :
“A note on Bayes estimates ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
38 : 6
(1967 ),
pp. 1907–1911 .
MR
0219175
Zbl
0155.26103
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Throughout this paper we are concerned with the problem of estimating a real parameter when the loss function is such that the Bayes estimate exists, is unique, and satisfies a simple Equation, (1.5). If the estimate is unbiased (in the general sense of [Lehmann 1951]) we show under weak conditions that it must satisfy another Equation, (1.14). The main result of Section 1, Theorem 1.3, shows that, in general, these two equations are incompatible unless the Bayes risk is 0. This extends Theorem 11.24 of [Blackwell and Girshick 1954] which states that in estimation with quadratic loss, unbiased Bayes estimates have Bayes risk 0. Some counter-examples at the end of the section indicate the limits of this incompatibility result.
@article {key0219175m,
AUTHOR = {Bickel, Peter J. and Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {A note on {B}ayes estimates},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {38},
NUMBER = {6},
YEAR = {1967},
PAGES = {1907--1911},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177698625},
NOTE = {MR:0219175. Zbl:0155.26103.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[60] D. Blackwell :
“Infinite games and analytic sets ,”
Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U.S.A.
58 : 5
(November 1967 ),
pp. 1836–1837 .
MR
0221466
Zbl
0224.90077
article
Abstract
BibTeX
@article {key0221466m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Infinite games and analytic sets},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. U.S.A.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the National Academy
of Sciences of the United States of
America},
VOLUME = {58},
NUMBER = {5},
MONTH = {November},
YEAR = {1967},
PAGES = {1836--1837},
DOI = {10.1073/pnas.58.5.1836},
NOTE = {MR:0221466. Zbl:0224.90077.},
ISSN = {0027-8424},
}
[61] D. Blackwell and J. L. Hodges, Jr. :
“Elementary path counts ,”
Am. Math. Mon.
74 : 7
(August–September 1967 ),
pp. 801–804 .
Zbl
0155.02903
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key0155.02903z,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Hodges, Jr., J. L.},
TITLE = {Elementary path counts},
JOURNAL = {Am. Math. Mon.},
FJOURNAL = {The American Mathematical Monthly},
VOLUME = {74},
NUMBER = {7},
MONTH = {August--September},
YEAR = {1967},
PAGES = {801--804},
DOI = {10.2307/2315796},
NOTE = {Zbl:0155.02903.},
ISSN = {0002-9890},
}
[62] D. Blackwell :
“Positive dynamic programming ,”
pp. 415–418
in
Proceedings of the fifth Berkeley symposium on mathematical statististics and probability
(Berkeley, CA, 21 June–18 July 1965 ),
vol. I: Theory of statistics .
Edited by L. M. Le Cam and J. Neyman .
University of California Press (Berkeley and Los Angeles ),
1967 .
MR
0218104
Zbl
0189.19804
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0218104m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Positive dynamic programming},
BOOKTITLE = {Proceedings of the fifth {B}erkeley
symposium on mathematical statististics
and probability},
EDITOR = {Le Cam, Lucien Marie and Neyman, Jerzy},
VOLUME = {I: Theory of statistics},
PUBLISHER = {University of California Press},
ADDRESS = {Berkeley and Los Angeles},
YEAR = {1967},
PAGES = {415--418},
NOTE = {(Berkeley, CA, 21 June--18 July 1965).
MR:0218104. Zbl:0189.19804.},
}
[63] D. Blackwell and T. S. Ferguson :
“The big match ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
39
(1968 ),
pp. 159–163 .
MR
0223162
Zbl
0164.50305
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key0223162m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Ferguson, T. S.},
TITLE = {The big match},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {39},
YEAR = {1968},
PAGES = {159--163},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177698513},
NOTE = {MR:0223162. Zbl:0164.50305.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[64] D. Blackwell and D. Freedman :
“On the local behavior of Markov transition probabilities ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
39 : 6
(1968 ),
pp. 2123–2127 .
MR
0233429
Zbl
0175.46903
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( P(t) = P(t,i,j) \) be a semigroup of stochastic matrices on the countable set \( I = \{i,j,\dots\}. \) Suppose
\[ \lim_{t\to 0}P(t,i,i) = 1 \quad\text{for each }i \in I .\]
Fix one state \( a \in I \) and abbreviate \( f(t) = P(t,a,a) \) .
Suppose \( 0 < \varepsilon < 1 \) and \( f(1) \leq 1 - \varepsilon \) . Then
\[ \int_0^1 f(t)\,dt < 1 - \tfrac12 \varepsilon.\]
Suppose \( 0 < \varepsilon < 1/4 \) and \( f(1) \geq 1 - \varepsilon \) . Then, for all \( t \) in \( [0,1] \) ,
\begin{align*} f(t) &\geq \tfrac12[1 + (1 - 4\varepsilon)^{1/2}]\\ & = 1 - \varepsilon - \varepsilon^2 - O(\varepsilon^3). \end{align*}
Suppose \( 0 < \varepsilon < 1/4 \) and \( \int_0^1 f(t)\, dt \geq 1 - \varepsilon \) . Then
\[ f(t) > 1 - 2\varepsilon \quad\textit{for }0 \leq t \leq 1 .\]
Note: The last statement can be restated (using algebra) in this more attractive form: if \( 0 < \delta < 1/2 \) and \( f(1) \geq 1 - \delta + \delta^2 \) , then \( f(t) \geq 1 - \delta \) for \( 0\leq t \leq 1 \) .
@article {key0233429m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Freedman, David},
TITLE = {On the local behavior of {M}arkov transition
probabilities},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {39},
NUMBER = {6},
YEAR = {1968},
PAGES = {2123--2127},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177698042},
NOTE = {MR:0233429. Zbl:0175.46903.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[65] D. Blackwell :
“A Borel set not containing a graph ,”
Ann. Math. Stat.
39 : 4
(1968 ),
pp. 1345–1347 .
MR
0229451
Zbl
0177.48401
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Examples of Borel sets \( X, Y, B \) such that
\( B \subset X \times Y \) ,
the projection of \( B \) on \( X \) is \( X \) , but
for no Borel-measurable \( d \) mapping \( X \) into \( Y \) is the graph of \( d \) a subset of \( B \) ,
have been given by [Novikoff 1931; Sierpiński 1931; Addison 1958]. Such examples are of interest in dynamic programming (see for instance [Blackwell 1965]), since if we interpret \( X \) as the set of states of some system, \( Y \) as the set of available acts, and \( I_B(x,y) \) where \( I_B \) is the indicator of \( B \) , as your income if the system is in state \( x \) and you choose act \( y \) , you can earn 1 in every state, but there is no Borel measurable plan, i.e. function \( d \) from \( X \) into \( Y \) , with \( d(x) \) specifying the act to be chosen when the system is in state \( x \) , that earns 1 in every state.
This note presents a new example \( X \) , \( Y \) , \( B \) , simpler than those previously given. The proof that it is an example uses ideas from Addison’s construction, and a theorem of Gale and Stewart [1953] on infinite games of perfect information, and is somewhat more complicated than Addison’s
@article {key0229451m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {A {B}orel set not containing a graph},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Math. Stat.},
FJOURNAL = {Annals of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {39},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1968},
PAGES = {1345--1347},
DOI = {10.1214/aoms/1177698260},
NOTE = {MR:0229451. Zbl:0177.48401.},
ISSN = {0003-4851},
}
[66] D. Blackwell :
“Infinite \( G_{\delta} \) -games with imperfect information ,”
Zastos. Mat.
10
(1969 ),
pp. 99–101 .
MR
0243837
Zbl
0232.90068
article
BibTeX
@article {key0243837m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Infinite \$G_{\delta}\$-games with imperfect
information},
JOURNAL = {Zastos. Mat.},
FJOURNAL = {Zastosowania Matematyki},
VOLUME = {10},
YEAR = {1969},
PAGES = {99--101},
NOTE = {MR:0243837. Zbl:0232.90068.},
ISSN = {0044-1899},
}
[67] D. Blackwell :
Basic statistics .
McGraw-Hill (New York ),
1969 .
book
BibTeX
@book {key31621255,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Basic statistics},
PUBLISHER = {McGraw-Hill},
ADDRESS = {New York},
YEAR = {1969},
PAGES = {143},
ISBN = {9780070055315},
}
[68] D. Blackwell :
“On stationary policies ,”
J. R. Stat. Soc., Ser. C
133 : 1
(1970 ),
pp. 33–37 .
With discussion.
A Russian translation was published in Mathematika 14 :2 (1970) .
MR
0449711
article
Abstract
BibTeX
In dynamic programming, stationary policies are those whose choice at different times depends only on the current state occupied. The author proves that if there is an optimal policy, there is an optimal policy that is stationary. Several general comments are made, based on the facts established.
@article {key0449711m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {On stationary policies},
JOURNAL = {J. R. Stat. Soc., Ser. C},
FJOURNAL = {Journal of the Royal Statistical Society.
Series C. Applied Statistics},
VOLUME = {133},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1970},
PAGES = {33--37},
URL = {http://www.jstor.org/pss/2343810},
NOTE = {With discussion. A Russian translation
was published in \textit{Mathematika}
\textbf{14}:2 (1970). MR:0449711.},
ISSN = {0035-9254},
}
[69] D. Blekuell :
“On stationary policies ,”
Matematika
14 : 2
(1970 ),
pp. 155–159 .
Russian translation of article in J. R. Stat. Soc., Ser. C 133 :1 (1970) .
Zbl
0224.49019
article
BibTeX
@article {key0224.49019z,
AUTHOR = {Blekuell, D.},
TITLE = {On stationary policies},
JOURNAL = {Matematika},
VOLUME = {14},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1970},
PAGES = {155--159},
NOTE = {Russian translation of article in \textit{J.
R. Stat. Soc., Ser. C} \textbf{133}:1
(1970). Zbl:0224.49019.},
}
[70] D. Blackwell and D. Freedman :
“On the amount of variance needed to escape from a strip ,”
Ann. Probab.
1 : 5
(1973 ),
pp. 772–787 .
MR
0356214
Zbl
0293.60041
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key0356214m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Freedman, David},
TITLE = {On the amount of variance needed to
escape from a strip},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Probability},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {5},
YEAR = {1973},
PAGES = {772--787},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176996845},
NOTE = {MR:0356214. Zbl:0293.60041.},
ISSN = {0091-1798},
}
[71] D. Blackwell :
“Discreteness of Ferguson selections ,”
Ann. Statist.
1 : 2
(1973 ),
pp. 356–358 .
MR
0348905
Zbl
0276.62009
article
Abstract
BibTeX
In a fundamental paper on nonparametric Bayesian inference, Ferguson [1972] associated with each probability measure \( \alpha \) on a set \( S \) and each positive number \( c \) a way of selecting a probability measure on \( S \) at random. One of his interesting results is that his method selects a discrete distribution with probability 1. Ferguson’s proof uses an explicit representation of the gamma process; we present here a quite different and perhaps simpler proof.
@article {key0348905m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Discreteness of {F}erguson selections},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Statist.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Statistics},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1973},
PAGES = {356--358},
DOI = {10.1214/aos/1176342373},
NOTE = {MR:0348905. Zbl:0276.62009.},
ISSN = {0090-5364},
}
[72] D. Blackwell and J. B. MacQueen :
“Ferguson distributions via Pólya urn schemes ,”
Ann. Statist.
1 : 2
(1973 ),
pp. 353–355 .
MR
0362614
Zbl
0276.62010
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
The Pólya urn scheme is extended by allowing a continuum of colors. For the extended scheme, the distribution of colors after \( n \) draws is shown to converge as \( n \to \infty \) to a limiting discrete distribution \( \mu^\ast \) . The distribution of \( \mu^\ast \) is shown to be one introduced by Ferguson and, given \( \mu^\ast \) , the colors drawn from the urn are shown to be independent with distribution \( \mu^\ast \) .
@article {key0362614m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and MacQueen, James
B.},
TITLE = {Ferguson distributions via {P}\'olya
urn schemes},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Statist.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Statistics},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1973},
PAGES = {353--355},
DOI = {10.1214/aos/1176342372},
NOTE = {MR:0362614. Zbl:0276.62010.},
ISSN = {0090-5364},
}
[73] D. Blackwell, D. Freedman, and M. Orkin :
“The optimal reward operator in dynamic programming ,”
Ann. Probab.
2 : 5
(1974 ),
pp. 926–941 .
MR
0359818
Zbl
0318.49021
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Consider a dynamic programming problem with analytic state space \( S \) , analytic constraint set \( A \) , and semi-analytic reward function \( r(x, P, y) \) for \( (x, P)\in A \) and \( y\in S \) : namely, \( \{r > a\} \) is an analytic set for all \( a \) . Let \( Tf \) be the optimal reward in one move, with the modified reward function \( r(x, P, y) + f(y) \) . The optimal reward in \( n \) moves is shown to be \( T^n0 \) , a semi-analytic function on \( S \) . It is also shown that for any \( n \) and positive \( \varepsilon \) , there is an \( \varepsilon \) -optimal strategy for the \( n \) -move game, measurable on the \( \sigma \) -field generated by the analytic sets.
@article {key0359818m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Freedman, D. and Orkin,
M.},
TITLE = {The optimal reward operator in dynamic
programming},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Probability},
VOLUME = {2},
NUMBER = {5},
YEAR = {1974},
PAGES = {926--941},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176996558},
NOTE = {MR:0359818. Zbl:0318.49021.},
ISSN = {0091-1798},
}
[74] D. Blackwell and L. E. Dubins :
“On existence and non-existence of proper, regular, conditional distributions ,”
Ann. Probab.
3 : 5
(1975 ),
pp. 741–752 .
MR
0400320
Zbl
0348.60003
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
If \( \mathscr{A} \) is the tail, invariant, or symmetric field for discrete-time processes, or a field of the form \( \mathscr{F}_{t+} \) for continuous-time processes, then no countably additive, regular, conditional distribution given \( \mathscr{A} \) is proper. A notion of normal conditional distributions is given, and there always exist countably additive normal conditional distributions if \( \mathscr{A} \) is a countably generated sub \( \sigma \) -field of a standard space. The study incidentally shows that the Borel-measurable axiom of choice is false. Classically interesting subfields \( \mathscr{A} \) of \( \mathscr{B} \) possess certain desirable properties which are the defining properties for \( \mathscr{A} \) to be “regular” in \( \mathscr{B} \) .
@article {key0400320m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester
E.},
TITLE = {On existence and non-existence of proper,
regular, conditional distributions},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Probability},
VOLUME = {3},
NUMBER = {5},
YEAR = {1975},
PAGES = {741--752},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176996261},
NOTE = {MR:0400320. Zbl:0348.60003.},
ISSN = {0091-1798},
}
[75] D. Blackwell :
“The stochastic processes of Borel gambling and dynamic programming ,”
Ann. Statist.
4 : 2
(1976 ),
pp. 370–374 .
MR
0405557
Zbl
0331.93055
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Associated with any Borel gambling model \( G \) or dynamic programming model \( D \) is a corresponding class of stochastic processes \( M(G) \) or \( M(D) \) . Say that \( G(D) \) is regular if there is a \( D(G) \) with \( M(D) = M(G) \) . Necessary and sufficient conditions for regularity are given, and it is shown how to modify any model slightly to achieve regularity.
@article {key0405557m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The stochastic processes of {B}orel
gambling and dynamic programming},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Statist.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Statistics},
VOLUME = {4},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1976},
PAGES = {370--374},
DOI = {10.1214/aos/1176343412},
NOTE = {MR:0405557. Zbl:0331.93055.},
ISSN = {0090-5364},
}
[76] D. Blackwell :
“Borel-programmable functions ,”
Ann. Probab.
6 : 2
(1978 ),
pp. 321–324 .
MR
0460573
Zbl
0398.28002
article
Abstract
BibTeX
A new class of functions, the BP (Borel-programmable) functions, is defined. It is strictly larger than the class of Borel functions, but has some similar properties, including closure under composition. All BP functions are absolutely measurable. The class of BP sets (those with BP indicators) is a Borel field and is closed under operation A. The relation of BP sets to the R-sets of Kolmogorov is not treated.
@article {key0460573m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Borel-programmable functions},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
VOLUME = {6},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1978},
PAGES = {321--324},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176995576},
NOTE = {MR:0460573. Zbl:0398.28002.},
}
[77] D. Blackwell and M. A. Girshick :
Theory of games and statistical decisions ,
reprint edition.
Dover Books on Advanced Mathematics .
Dover Publications (New York ),
1979 .
Republication of 1954 original .
MR
597146
Zbl
0439.62008
book
People
BibTeX
@book {key597146m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Girshick, M. A.},
TITLE = {Theory of games and statistical decisions},
EDITION = {reprint},
SERIES = {Dover Books on Advanced Mathematics},
PUBLISHER = {Dover Publications},
ADDRESS = {New York},
YEAR = {1979},
PAGES = {xi+355},
NOTE = {Republication of 1954 original. MR:597146.
Zbl:0439.62008.},
ISBN = {9780486638317},
}
[78] D. Blackwell :
“There are no Borel SPLIFs ,”
Ann. Probab.
8 : 6
(1980 ),
pp. 1189–1190 .
MR
602393
Zbl
0451.28001
article
Abstract
BibTeX
There is no Borel function \( f \) , defined for all infinite sequences of 0s and 1s, such that for every sequence \( X \) of 0–1 random variables that converges in probability to a constant \( c \) , we have \( f(x) = c \) a.s.
@article {key602393m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {There are no {B}orel {SPLIF}s},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Probability},
VOLUME = {8},
NUMBER = {6},
YEAR = {1980},
PAGES = {1189--1190},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176994581},
NOTE = {MR:602393. Zbl:0451.28001.},
ISSN = {0091-1798},
CODEN = {APBYAE},
}
[79] D. Blackwell :
“Borel sets via games ,”
Ann. Probab.
9 : 2
(1981 ),
pp. 321–322 .
MR
606995
Zbl
0455.28002
article
Abstract
BibTeX
A family of games \( G = G(\sigma, u) \) is defined such that (a) for each \( \sigma \) the set of all \( u \) for which Player I can force a win in \( G(\sigma, u) \) is a Borel set \( B(u) \) and (b) every Borel set is a \( B(u) \) for some \( u \) .
@article {key606995m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Borel sets via games},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Probab.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Probability},
VOLUME = {9},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1981},
PAGES = {321--322},
DOI = {10.1214/aop/1176994474},
NOTE = {MR:606995. Zbl:0455.28002.},
ISSN = {0091-1798},
CODEN = {APBYAE},
}
[80] D. Blackwell and R. V. Ramamoorthi :
“A Bayes but not classically sufficient statistic ,”
Ann. Statist.
10 : 3
(1982 ),
pp. 1025–1026 .
MR
663456
Zbl
0485.62004
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
In a Borel setting, every classically sufficient statistic is Bayes sufficient, but not vice versa. The example is a hypothesis testing problem in which Bayesians, but not classicists, can achieve zero error probabilities.
@article {key663456m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Ramamoorthi, R. V.},
TITLE = {A {B}ayes but not classically sufficient
statistic},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Statist.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Statistics},
VOLUME = {10},
NUMBER = {3},
YEAR = {1982},
PAGES = {1025--1026},
DOI = {10.1214/aos/1176345895},
NOTE = {MR:663456. Zbl:0485.62004.},
ISSN = {0090-5364},
CODEN = {ASTSC7},
}
[81] D. Blackwell and L. E. Dubins :
“An extension of Skorohod’s almost sure representation theorem ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
89 : 4
(1983 ),
pp. 691–692 .
MR
718998
Zbl
0542.60005
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Skorohod discovered that if a sequence \( Q_n \) of countably additive probabilities on a Polish space converges in the weak star topology, then, on a standard probability space, there are \( Q_n \) -distributed \( f_n \) which converge almost surely. This note strengthens Skorohod’s result by associating, with each probability \( Q \) on a Polish space, a random variable \( f_Q \) on a fixed standard probability space so that for each \( Q \) ,
\( f_Q \) has distribution \( Q \) and
with probability 1, \( f_P \) is continuous at \( P = Q \) .
@article {key718998m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Dubins, Lester
E.},
TITLE = {An extension of {S}korohod's almost
sure representation theorem},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {89},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1983},
PAGES = {691--692},
DOI = {10.2307/2044607},
URL = {http://www.ams.org/journals/proc/1983-089-04/S0002-9939-1983-0718998-0/S0002-9939-1983-0718998-0.pdf},
NOTE = {MR:718998. Zbl:0542.60005.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
CODEN = {PAMYAR},
}
[82] D. Blackwell :
“A hypothesis-testing game without a value ,”
pp. 79–82
in
A Festschrift for Erich L. Lehmann .
Edited by P. J. Bickel, K. A. Doksum, and J. L. Hodges .
Wadsworth Statistics/Probability Series .
Wadsworth (Belmont, CA ),
1983 .
MR
689739
Zbl
0525.62006
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key689739m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {A hypothesis-testing game without a
value},
BOOKTITLE = {A {F}estschrift for {E}rich~{L}. {L}ehmann},
EDITOR = {Bickel, Peter J. and Doksum, Kjell A.
and Hodges, Joseph Lawson},
SERIES = {Wadsworth Statistics/Probability Series},
PUBLISHER = {Wadsworth},
ADDRESS = {Belmont, CA},
YEAR = {1983},
PAGES = {79--82},
NOTE = {MR:689739. Zbl:0525.62006.},
ISBN = {9780534980443},
}
[83] D. Blackwell and A. Maitra :
“Factorization of probability measures and absolutely measurable sets ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
92 : 2
(1984 ),
pp. 251–254 .
MR
754713
Zbl
0554.60001
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
We find necessary and sufficient conditions for a separable metric space \( Y \) to possess the property that for any measurable space \( (X,\mathcal{A}) \) and probability measure \( P \) on \( X \times Y \) , \( P \) can be factored.
@article {key754713m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Maitra, Ashok},
TITLE = {Factorization of probability measures
and absolutely measurable sets},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {92},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1984},
PAGES = {251--254},
DOI = {10.2307/2045195},
NOTE = {MR:754713. Zbl:0554.60001.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
CODEN = {PAMYAR},
}
[84] D. Blackwell :
Approximate normality of large products .
Preprint 54 ,
U.C. Berkeley Statistics Department (Berkeley, CA ),
1985 .
techreport
BibTeX
@techreport {key42487139,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Approximate normality of large products},
TYPE = {Preprint},
NUMBER = {54},
INSTITUTION = {U.C. Berkeley Statistics Department},
ADDRESS = {Berkeley, CA},
YEAR = {1985},
}
[85] “David Harold Blackwell ,”
pp. 18–32
in
Mathematical people: Profiles and interviews .
Edited by D. J. Albers and G. L. Alexanderson .
AK Peters/CRC Press (Boston ),
1985 .
Interview by Donald J. Albers.
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key56408007,
TITLE = {David {H}arold {B}lackwell},
BOOKTITLE = {Mathematical people: {P}rofiles and
interviews},
EDITOR = {Albers, D. J. and Alexanderson, G. L.},
PUBLISHER = {AK Peters/CRC Press},
ADDRESS = {Boston},
YEAR = {1985},
PAGES = {18--32},
NOTE = {Interview by Donald~J. Albers.},
ISBN = {9781568813400},
}
[86] D. Blackwell and R. D. Mauldin :
“Ulam’s redistribution of energy problem: Collision transformations ,”
pp. 149–153
in
In memory of Stan Ulam ,
published as Lett. Math. Phys.
10 : 2–3
(1985 ).
MR
815237
Zbl
0582.60035
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Ulam conjectured that for each given law of redistribution of energy, \( D \) , there corresponds a limiting distribution, \( C(D) \) , the “collision transform” of the given law such that if \( X \) is an initial distribution of energy, then the distributions of the iterates of \( X \) under redistribution, converge to \( C(D) \) . We give examples of this behaviour and prove that Ulam’s conjecture is correct in case all moments of \( X \) exists.
@article {key815237m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Mauldin, R. Daniel},
TITLE = {Ulam's redistribution of energy problem:
{C}ollision transformations},
JOURNAL = {Lett. Math. Phys.},
FJOURNAL = {Letters in Mathematical Physics},
VOLUME = {10},
NUMBER = {2--3},
YEAR = {1985},
PAGES = {149--153},
DOI = {10.1007/BF00398151},
NOTE = {\textit{In memory of {S}tan {U}lam}.
MR:815237. Zbl:0582.60035.},
ISSN = {0377-9017},
CODEN = {LMPDHQ},
}
[87] M. H. DeGroot :
“A conversation with David Blackwell ,”
Statist. Sci.
1 : 1
(1986 ),
pp. 40–53 .
MR
833274
Zbl
0597.01014
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Read it here
@article {key833274m,
AUTHOR = {DeGroot, Morris H.},
TITLE = {A conversation with {D}avid {B}lackwell},
JOURNAL = {Statist. Sci.},
FJOURNAL = {Statistical Science. A Review Journal
of the Institute of Mathematical Statistics},
VOLUME = {1},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1986},
PAGES = {40--53},
DOI = {10.1214/ss/1177013814},
NOTE = {MR:833274. Zbl:0597.01014.},
ISSN = {0883-4237},
}
[88] D. Blackwell and S. Ramakrishnan :
“Stationary plans need not be uniformly adequate for leavable, Borel gambling problems ,”
Proc. Am. Math. Soc.
102 : 4
(1988 ),
pp. 1024–1027 .
MR
934886
Zbl
0658.60072
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
There exists a leavable, Borel gambling problem with a goal, where at most three gambles are available at each fortune, where each gamble has at most two points in its support, but for which stationary plans are not uniformly adequate.
@article {key934886m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D. and Ramakrishnan, S.},
TITLE = {Stationary plans need not be uniformly
adequate for leavable, {B}orel gambling
problems},
JOURNAL = {Proc. Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Proceedings of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {102},
NUMBER = {4},
YEAR = {1988},
PAGES = {1024--1027},
DOI = {10.2307/2047353},
NOTE = {MR:934886. Zbl:0658.60072.},
ISSN = {0002-9939},
CODEN = {PAMYAR},
}
[89] D. Blackwell :
“Operator solution of infinite \( G_\delta \) games of imperfect information ,”
pp. 83–87
in
Probability, statistics, and mathematics: Papers in honor of Samuel Karlin .
Edited by T. W. Anderson, K. B. Athreya, and D. L. Iglehart .
Academic Press (Boston, MA ),
1989 .
MR
1031279
Zbl
0696.90094
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key1031279m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Operator solution of infinite \$G_\delta\$
games of imperfect information},
BOOKTITLE = {Probability, statistics, and mathematics:
{P}apers in honor of {S}amuel {K}arlin},
EDITOR = {Anderson, Theodore Wilbur and Athreya,
Krishna B. and Iglehart, Donald L.},
PUBLISHER = {Academic Press},
ADDRESS = {Boston, MA},
YEAR = {1989},
PAGES = {83--87},
NOTE = {MR:1031279. Zbl:0696.90094.},
ISBN = {9780120584703},
}
[90] M. Proschan :
“A note on D. H. Blackwell and J. L. Hodges, Jr.: ‘Design for the control of selection bias’, and P. Diaconis and R. L. Graham: ‘The analysis of sequential experiments with feedback to subjects’ ,”
Ann. Statist.
19 : 2
(1991 ),
pp. 1106–1108 .
The paper of Diaconis and Graham is Ann. Statist. 9 :1 (1981) pp. 3–23.
Commentary on Ann. Math. Stat. 28 :2 (1957) .
MR
1105868
Zbl
0747.62021
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@article {key1105868m,
AUTHOR = {Proschan, Michael},
TITLE = {A note on {D}.~{H}. {B}lackwell and
{J}.~{L}. {H}odges, {J}r.: ``{D}esign
for the control of selection bias'',
and {P}.~{D}iaconis and {R}.~{L}. {G}raham:
``{T}he analysis of sequential experiments
with feedback to subjects''},
JOURNAL = {Ann. Statist.},
FJOURNAL = {The Annals of Statistics},
VOLUME = {19},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {1991},
PAGES = {1106--1108},
DOI = {10.1214/aos/1176348144},
NOTE = {The paper of Diaconis and Graham is
\textit{Ann. Statist.} \textbf{9}:1
(1981) pp. 3--23. Commentary on \textit{Ann.
Math. Stat.} \textbf{28}:2 (1957). MR:1105868.
Zbl:0747.62021.},
ISSN = {0090-5364},
CODEN = {ASTSC7},
}
[91] D. Blackwell :
“Minimax vs. Bayes prediction ,”
Probab. Engrg. Inform. Sci.
9 : 1
(1995 ),
pp. 53–58 .
Available open access
here .
MR
1336801
article
Abstract
BibTeX
Let \( x = (x_1, x_2, \dots) \) be an infinite sequence of 0s and 1s, initially unknown to you. On day \( n = 1 \) , \( 2,\dots \) , you observe \( h_n= (x_1,\dots \) , \( x_{n-1}) \) , the first \( n-1 \) terms of the sequence, and must predict \( x_n \) . What is a good prediction method, and how well can you do?
@article {key1336801m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Minimax vs.\ {B}ayes prediction},
JOURNAL = {Probab. Engrg. Inform. Sci.},
FJOURNAL = {Probability in the Engineering and Informational
Sciences},
VOLUME = {9},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {1995},
PAGES = {53--58},
DOI = {10.1017/S0269964800003685},
NOTE = {Available open access at http://ljsavage.wharton.upenn.edu/~steele/Resources/Projects/SequenceProject/Blackwell/BlackwellLecture.pdf.
MR:1336801.},
ISSN = {0269-9648},
}
[92] D. Blackwell :
“Games with infinitely many moves and slightly imperfect information ,”
pp. 407–408
in
Games of no chance
(MSRI, Berkeley, CA 11–21 July 1994 ).
Edited by R. J. Nowakowski .
MSRI Publications 29 .
Cambridge University Press ,
1996 .
Zbl
0873.90115
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key0873.90115z,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Games with infinitely many moves and
slightly imperfect information},
BOOKTITLE = {Games of no chance},
EDITOR = {Nowakowski, Richard J.},
SERIES = {MSRI Publications},
NUMBER = {29},
PUBLISHER = {Cambridge University Press},
YEAR = {1996},
PAGES = {407--408},
NOTE = {(MSRI, Berkeley, CA 11--21 July 1994).
Zbl:0873.90115.},
ISBN = {9780521574112},
}
[93] D. Blackwell and P. Diaconis :
“A non-measurable tail set ,”
pp. 1–5
in
Statistics, probability and game theory: Papers in honor of David Blackwell .
Edited by T. S. Ferguson, L. S. Shapley, and J. B. MacQueen .
IMS Lecture Notes–Monograph Series 30 .
Institute of Mathematical Statistics (Hayward, CA ),
1996 .
MR
1481768
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key1481768m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David and Diaconis, Persi},
TITLE = {A non-measurable tail set},
BOOKTITLE = {Statistics, probability and game theory:
{P}apers in honor of {D}avid {B}lackwell},
EDITOR = {Ferguson, T. S. and Shapley, L. S. and
MacQueen, J. B.},
SERIES = {IMS Lecture Notes -- Monograph Series},
NUMBER = {30},
PUBLISHER = {Institute of Mathematical Statistics},
ADDRESS = {Hayward, CA},
YEAR = {1996},
PAGES = {1--5},
DOI = {10.1214/lnms/1215453560},
NOTE = {MR:1481768.},
ISBN = {9780940600423},
}
[94] T. S. Ferguson, L. S. Shapley, and J. B. MacQueen :
“Preface [Biography of David Blackwell] ,”
pp. v–xiv
in
Statistics, probability and game theory: Papers in honor of David Blackwell .
Edited by T. S. Ferguson, L. S. Shapley, and J. B. MacQueen .
IMS Lecture Notes–Monograph Series 30 .
Institute of Mathematical Statistics (Hayward, CA ),
1996 .
MR
1481767
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
This volume has been created to honor Professor David Blackwell of the University of California at Berkeley by his students, colleagues, friends and admirers. Most of the papers of this volume are on topics connected with areas in which Blackwell has played a major role. There are review articles on Comparison of Experiments, on Games of Timing, on Merging of Opinions, on Associate Memory Models, and SPLIFs etc. There are historical views of Carnap, of von Mises, and of the Berkeley Statistics Department. But the bulk of the articles are research articles in Probability, Statistics, Gambling, Game Theory, Markov Decision Processes, Set Theory and Logic. Special care has been taken to achieve a wide variety of readable and interesting papers from outstanding scholars.
We present a brief biography of Blackwell, followed by a short review of his research accomplishments. We also include a bibliography of his publications, which, as may be seen from the first article of this volume, becomes out of date with the publication of this volume
@incollection {key1481767m,
AUTHOR = {Ferguson, Thomas S. and Shapley, Lloyd
S. and MacQueen, James B.},
TITLE = {Preface [{B}iography of {D}avid {B}lackwell]},
BOOKTITLE = {Statistics, probability and game theory:
{P}apers in honor of {D}avid {B}lackwell},
EDITOR = {Ferguson, T. S. and Shapley, L. S. and
MacQueen, J. B.},
SERIES = {IMS Lecture Notes -- Monograph Series},
NUMBER = {30},
PUBLISHER = {Institute of Mathematical Statistics},
ADDRESS = {Hayward, CA},
YEAR = {1996},
PAGES = {v--xiv},
NOTE = {MR:1481767.},
ISBN = {9780940600423},
}
[95] Statistics, probability and game theory: Papers in honor of David Blackwell .
Edited by T. S. Ferguson, L. S. Shapley, and J. B. MacQueen .
IMS Lecture Notes–Monograph Series 30 .
Institute of Mathematical Statistics (Hayward, CA ),
1996 .
MR
1481766
Zbl
0996.60500
book
People
BibTeX
@book {key1481766m,
TITLE = {Statistics, probability and game theory:
{P}apers in honor of David Blackwell},
EDITOR = {Ferguson, T. S. and Shapley, L. S. and
MacQueen, J. B.},
SERIES = {IMS Lecture Notes -- Monograph Series},
NUMBER = {30},
PUBLISHER = {Institute of Mathematical Statistics},
ADDRESS = {Hayward, CA},
YEAR = {1996},
PAGES = {xiv+407},
NOTE = {MR:1481766. Zbl:0996.60500.},
ISBN = {9780940600423},
}
[96] K. W. Wachter, D. Blackwell, and E. A. Hammel :
“Testing the validity of kinship microsimulation ,”
Math. Comput. Modelling
26 : 6
(1997 ),
pp. 89–104 .
Zbl
0884.92034
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Computer microsimulation is capable of generating detailed reconstructions and forecasts of the numbers of living kin that members of a population have. The available detail, specificity, and consistency of vital rates for the past and the accuracy of vital rates projected for the future necessarily limit the accuracy of the kinship estimates that can be produced.
This study is an external validity test of Reeves’ 1982 reconstruction and forecast of U.S. kin counts with the SOCSIM microsimulation program [Reeves 1982]. The external standard is provided by estimates from the 1987-1988 wave of the National Survey of Families and Households, the first detailed information on numbers and ages of kin for the United States. We compare forecasts with estimates for average numbers of living grandchildren, living full-siblings, and living half-siblings as functions of age.
We find remarkably close agreement for some of the predictions, along with several instances of systematic discrepancies. The discrepancies most likely stem from errors in the forecasts rather than in the survey estimates. Interacting rather than isolable errors appear to be responsible. Our validity tests provide a basis for qualified faith in the effectiveness of kinship microsimulation.
@article {key0884.92034z,
AUTHOR = {Wachter, K. W. and Blackwell, D. and
Hammel, E. A.},
TITLE = {Testing the validity of kinship microsimulation},
JOURNAL = {Math. Comput. Modelling},
FJOURNAL = {Mathematical and Computer Modelling},
VOLUME = {26},
NUMBER = {6},
YEAR = {1997},
PAGES = {89--104},
DOI = {10.1016/S0895-7177(97)00172-6},
NOTE = {Zbl:0884.92034.},
ISSN = {0895-7177},
}
[97] D. Blackwell :
“Large deviations for martingales ,”
pp. 89–91
in
Festschrift for Lucien Le Cam .
Edited by D. Pollard, E. N. Torgersen, and G. L. Yang .
Springer (New York ),
1997 .
MR
1462940
Zbl
0883.60041
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Let \( X_1, X_2, \dots \) be variables satisfying
\( |x_n| \leq 1 \) and
\( E(X_n\mid X_1,\dots,X_{n-1})=0 \) ,
and put \( S_n = X_1 + \dots+ X_n \) .
For any positive constants \( a \) and \( b \) ,
\[ P\{S_n \geq a + bn \textit{ for some } n\} \leq \exp(-2ab) .\]
For any positive constant \( c \) ,
\[ P\{S_n \geq cn \textit{ for some } n \geq N\} \leq r_1^N \leq r_2^N ,\]
where
\[ r_1 = \frac{1}{((1+c)^{1+c}(1-c)^{1-c})^{1/2}} \quad\text{and}\quad r_2 = \exp(-c^2/2) .\]
@incollection {key1462940m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, D.},
TITLE = {Large deviations for martingales},
BOOKTITLE = {Festschrift for {L}ucien {L}e~{C}am},
EDITOR = {Pollard, David and Torgersen, Erik N.
and Yang, Grace Lo},
PUBLISHER = {Springer},
ADDRESS = {New York},
YEAR = {1997},
PAGES = {89--91},
NOTE = {MR:1462940. Zbl:0883.60041.},
ISBN = {9780387949529},
}
[98] Learning in games: A symposium in honor of David Blackwell ,
published as Games Econom. Behav.
29 : 1/2 .
Issue edited by D. P. Foster, D. K. Levine, and R. V. Vohra .
Elsevier (San Diego, CA ),
1999 .
MR
1729307
Zbl
1131.91300
book
People
BibTeX
@book {key1729307m,
TITLE = {Learning in games: {A} symposium in
honor of {D}avid {B}lackwell},
EDITOR = {Foster, Dean P. and Levine, David K.
and Vohra, Rakesh V.},
PUBLISHER = {Elsevier},
ADDRESS = {San Diego, CA},
YEAR = {1999},
PAGES = {i, 1--316},
NOTE = {Published as \textit{Games Econom. Behav.}
\textbf{29}:1/2. MR:1729307. Zbl:1131.91300.},
ISSN = {0899-8256},
}
[99] D. Blackwell :
“The square-root game ,”
pp. 35–37
in
Game theory, optimal stopping, probability and statistics: Papers in honor of Thomas S. Ferguson .
Edited by F. T. Bruss and L. Le Cam .
IMS Lecture Notes–Monograph Series 35 .
Institute of Mathematical Statististis (Beachwood, OH ),
2000 .
MR
1833849
Zbl
0988.91004
incollection
Abstract
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key1833849m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The square-root game},
BOOKTITLE = {Game theory, optimal stopping, probability
and statistics: {P}apers in honor of
{T}homas~{S}. {F}erguson},
EDITOR = {Bruss, F. Thomas and Le Cam, Lucien},
SERIES = {IMS Lecture Notes -- Monograph Series},
NUMBER = {35},
PUBLISHER = {Institute of Mathematical Statististis},
ADDRESS = {Beachwood, OH},
YEAR = {2000},
PAGES = {35--37},
DOI = {10.1214/lnms/1215089742},
NOTE = {MR:1833849. Zbl:0988.91004.},
ISBN = {9780940600485},
}
[100] D. Blackwell :
“Large excesses for finite-state Markov chains ,”
pp. 35–39
in
System and Bayesian reliability: Essays in honor of Professor Richard E. Barlow on his 70th birthday .
Edited by Y. Hayakawa, T. Irony, and M. Xie .
Series on Quality, Reliability & Engineering statistics 5 .
World Scientific (River Edge, NJ ),
2001 .
MR
1896774
incollection
People
BibTeX
@incollection {key1896774m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {Large excesses for finite-state {M}arkov
chains},
BOOKTITLE = {System and {B}ayesian reliability: {E}ssays
in honor of {P}rofessor {R}ichard~{E}.
{B}arlow on his 70th birthday},
EDITOR = {Hayakawa, Yu and Irony, Telba and Xie,
Min},
SERIES = {Series on Quality, Reliability \& Engineering
statistics},
NUMBER = {5},
PUBLISHER = {World Scientific},
ADDRESS = {River Edge, NJ},
YEAR = {2001},
PAGES = {35--39},
DOI = {10.1142/9789812799548_0003},
NOTE = {MR:1896774.},
ISBN = {9789810248659},
}
[101] D. Blackwell :
“The prediction of sequences ,”
Internat. J. Game Theory
31 : 2
(2002 ),
pp. 245–251 .
Special anniversary issue.
MR
1968990
Zbl
1082.91036
article
Abstract
BibTeX
The problem of predicting the short-term future behavior of a sequence, after observing it as long as we please, so as to achieve a specified reliability against all possible sequences is considered. For a particular problem, namely, predicting when in a sequence of 0s and 1s the pair \( (1,0) \) in that order is not coming next, a reliability of \( 3/4 \) can be approximated as closely as we please, but not achieved.
@article {key1968990m,
AUTHOR = {Blackwell, David},
TITLE = {The prediction of sequences},
JOURNAL = {Internat. J. Game Theory},
FJOURNAL = {International Journal of Game Theory},
VOLUME = {31},
NUMBER = {2},
YEAR = {2002},
PAGES = {245--251},
DOI = {10.1007/s001820200114},
NOTE = {Special anniversary issue. MR:1968990.
Zbl:1082.91036.},
ISSN = {0020-7276},
CODEN = {IJGTA2},
}
[102] N. Agwu, L. Smith, and A. Barry :
“Dr. David Harold Blackwell, African American pioneer ,”
Math. Mag.
76 : 1
(2003 ),
pp. 3–14 .
MR
2084114
article
Abstract
People
BibTeX
Dr. David Blackwell is an African American educational pioneer and eminent scholar in the fields of mathematics and statistics, whose contributions to our society extend beyond these fields. This paper highlights his significant contributions and the personal, educational, and professional experiences that groomed and nurtured him for leadership as a civic scientist. We hope this account of Dr. Blackwell’s life will enhance the literature on African American achievers, and motivate students majoring in, or considering careers in mathematics and statistics, particularly those from underrepresented groups.
@article {key2084114m,
AUTHOR = {Agwu, Nkechi and Smith, Luella and Barry,
Aissatou},
TITLE = {Dr.\ {D}avid {H}arold {B}lackwell, {A}frican
{A}merican pioneer},
JOURNAL = {Math. Mag.},
FJOURNAL = {Mathematics Magazine},
VOLUME = {76},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {2003},
PAGES = {3--14},
DOI = {10.2307/3219127},
NOTE = {MR:2084114.},
ISSN = {0025-570X},
CODEN = {MAMGA8},
}
[103] M. Bhattacharjee, R. Lockhart, J. Rolph, G. Roussas, H. Tucker, R. J.-B. Wets, P. Bickel, T. S. Ferguson, A. Lo, M. L. Puri, S. Stigler, W. Sudderth, Y. Yatracos, D. Brillinger, L. A. Goodman, J. Shaffer, H. Chernoff, P. Diaconis, M. Rosenblatt, and F. J. Samaniego :
“A tribute to David Blackwell .”
Edited by G. G. Roussas .
Notices Am. Math. Soc.
58 : 7
(2011 ),
pp. 912–928 .
MR
2850553
Zbl
1225.01082
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key2850553m,
AUTHOR = {Bhattacharjee, Manish and Lockhart,
Richard and Rolph, John and Roussas,
George and Tucker, Howard and Wets,
Roger J.-B. and Bickel, Peter and Ferguson,
Thomas S. and Lo, Albert and Puri, Madan
L. and Stigler, Stephen and Sudderth,
W. and Yatracos, Yannis and Brillinger,
David and Goodman, Leo A. and Shaffer,
Juliet and Chernoff, Herman and Diaconis,
Persi and Rosenblatt, Murray and Samaniego,
Francisco J.},
TITLE = {A tribute to {D}avid {B}lackwell},
JOURNAL = {Notices Am. Math. Soc.},
FJOURNAL = {Notices of the American Mathematical
Society},
VOLUME = {58},
NUMBER = {7},
YEAR = {2011},
PAGES = {912--928},
URL = {http://www.ams.org/notices/201107/rtx110700912p.pdf},
NOTE = {Edited by G. G. Roussas.
MR:2850553. Zbl:1225.01082.},
ISSN = {0002-9920},
CODEN = {AMNOAN},
}
[104] R. Swift :
“Obituary: David Blackwell ,”
Math. Sci.
36 : 1
(2011 ),
pp. 70–71 .
MR
2829586
Zbl
1228.01049
article
People
BibTeX
@article {key2829586m,
AUTHOR = {Swift, Randall},
TITLE = {Obituary: {D}avid {B}lackwell},
JOURNAL = {Math. Sci.},
FJOURNAL = {The Mathematical Scientist},
VOLUME = {36},
NUMBER = {1},
YEAR = {2011},
PAGES = {70--71},
NOTE = {MR:2829586. Zbl:1228.01049.},
ISSN = {0312-3685},
}